• Search Menu
  • Sign in through your institution
  • Author Guidelines
  • Submission Site
  • Open Access
  • About International Studies Review
  • About the International Studies Association
  • Editorial Board
  • Advertising and Corporate Services
  • Journals Career Network
  • Self-Archiving Policy
  • Dispatch Dates
  • Journals on Oxford Academic
  • Books on Oxford Academic

Issue Cover

Article Contents

Introduction, literature review on sanction consequences, limitations of existing research, new perspectives and new directions for the research, acknowledgments.

  • < Previous

Consequences of Economic Sanctions: The State of the Art and Paths Forward

ORCID logo

  • Article contents
  • Figures & tables
  • Supplementary Data

Özgür Özdamar, Evgeniia Shahin, Consequences of Economic Sanctions: The State of the Art and Paths Forward, International Studies Review , Volume 23, Issue 4, December 2021, Pages 1646–1671, https://doi.org/10.1093/isr/viab029

  • Permissions Icon Permissions

What determines the consequences of economic sanctions? Is there a common explanation for these consequences? This article provides a comprehensive review of the fragmented literature focusing on the consequences of sanctions. We critically discuss the complex relationships between types of sanctions and sanction senders and their targets, as well as the structural factors that account for the specific consequences of different sanction cases. A discussion on the thematic, methodological, and theoretical shortcomings of the existing literature on sanction consequences follows. We argue that a “common approach” to sanction consequences research should be framed within the framework of international interdependence. We also present several nascent trends and propose new directions for sanction researchers and other disciplines.

¿Qué determina las consecuencias de las sanciones económicas? ¿Existe una explicación común para estas consecuencias? Este artículo proporciona un análisis completo de la literatura fragmentada centrándose en las consecuencias de las sanciones. Tratamos de manera crítica las relaciones complejas entre los tipos de sanciones y los responsables de imponerlas y los receptores, así como los factores estructurales que explican las consecuencias específicas de los diferentes casos de sanciones. A continuación, se incluye un debate sobre los defectos temáticos, metodológicos y teóricos de la literatura existente sobre las consecuencias de las sanciones. Sostenemos que debería plantearse un “enfoque común” para la investigación sobre las consecuencias de las sanciones dentro del marco de la interdependencia internacional. También presentamos varias tendencias nacientes y proponemos nuevas orientaciones para los investigadores de sanciones y otras disciplinas.

Par quoi les conséquences des sanctions économiques sont-elles déterminées? Existe-t-il une explication commune de ces conséquences? Cet article propose un examen complet de la littérature fragmentée se concentrant sur les conséquences des sanctions. Nous abordons d'un œil critique les relations complexes entre les types de sanctions et les émetteurs de sanctions et leurs cibles, ainsi que les facteurs structurels qui expliquent les conséquences spécifiques des différents cas de sanctions. Nous poursuivons par une discussion sur les lacunes thématiques, méthodologiques et théoriques de la littérature existante sur les conséquences des sanctions. Nous soutenons qu'une « approche commune » des recherches sur les conséquences des sanctions devrait s'inscrire dans le cadre de l'interdépendance internationale. Nous présentons également plusieurs tendances naissantes et nous proposons de nouvelles orientations pour les chercheurs spécialisés en sanctions et les autres disciplines.

Economic sanctions are increasingly used in international relations. Research on sanction consequences is growing and already covers many issues and areas. However, our understanding of the various impacts of sanctions on different actors (including targets, sanction senders, other states, individuals, groups, and systems) remains limited due to the fragmentation of the existing research along the different approaches or subtopics.

To understand the state of the art of sanction consequences research, we provide a rare comprehensive review of sanction consequences literature. While a recent essay by Allen et al. (2020) evaluates some advances and policy implications of the latest research in this area, we present a broader critical review of sanction effects for all actors and on a systemic level discuss the conflicting findings, limitations, and paths forwards. We bring together works on different influenced entities, different types of sanctions and their consequences, and different methodologies and data. As no review can cover all the research on sanction consequences, we attempt to present selected works covering the broadest possible range of sanction impacts in different areas. The breadth of the literature review aims to demonstrate the fragmentation of the literature and to integrate otherwise rarely communicating works from different approaches. Moreover, it shows that different subareas of sanction consequences research may benefit from common insights. After critically reviewing the existing research on economic, political, humanitarian, and social and systemic consequences, we discuss the main weaknesses and limitations of the current research.

We identify several problematic thematic, methodological, and theoretical issues in the sanction consequences literature. We argue that while a parsimonious theory of sanctions is difficult to achieve, accounting for the interdependence between sanction senders, targets, and other states can explain the lack of consistency between different findings, as well as facilitate dialogue among methodologically different works. Most importantly, focusing on interdependence may allow one to connect the most distinct branches of sanction consequences research and improve one's understanding of each.

Therefore, we propose a common approach (as opposed to a comprehensive theory) to study sanction consequences by accounting for different degrees of interconnectedness and interdependence between the sender/target and other states. Building upon the logic of the asymmetrical network-based interdependence approach ( Farrell and Newman 2019 ), we argue that what combines sanction consequences research is that sanctions are conducted within the context of interdependent actors located within multiple hierarchical networks and possessing different capacities for restricting economic transactions or adjusting to them. Moreover, we show how newly developing issues (such as the use of cryptocurrencies or migration flows) not yet fully tackled by sanction consequences research can fit within the scope of an understanding of interdependence and its influence on sanctions, their impacts, and their outcomes. A focus on network-based interdependence could shed light on the target's capacity to strengthen its own relations with other states by creating new economic networks. Locating sanctions within such a framework of interdependence will allow for a better understanding of the effects of secondary sanctions and sanction boosters. It may also help evaluate the adaptation capacity of third states connected to the economic network, as well as the systemic consequences related to the global changes within the economic and financial networks.

In the following sections, we review the existing literature on sanction consequences, focusing on the political, economic, humanitarian, and other (such as social) consequences for different actors and the international level. We acknowledge that as many sanction impacts are interlinked, focusing on these types represents a rather approximate categorization. We discuss the relevant findings within each broader type of sanction consequence to make it easier to identify the connection between sanction impacts for different actors. Then we discuss the main shortcomings of the literature and point to directions for the further advancement of sanction consequences research. In the third section, we present the framework of networked interdependence as a common approach to analyzing sanction consequences and show the intertwined relations between all the actors involved. Finally, we synthesize our main observations about sanction consequences research and discuss the paths forward.

Economic sanctions can be defined as restrictions over economic activity imposed by one international actor on another with a specific purpose. Purposes of sanctions may include “signaling” one's message to targeted or third states, enforcing a behavioral change (“coercion”), “constraining” one's behavior ( Giumelli 2011 , 32–35), meeting other goals, 1 or achieving combinations of different purposes. The actors involved may include not only the sanctioning and targeted states, but also the international organizations among senders, nonstate actors (specific groups within the state, terrorist organizations, or even specific people among targets), and third-party states. We consider third-party states, or states not participating in sanctions or involuntarily taking part in their enforcement (for example, in the mandatory United Nations sanctions) because the increasing use of secondary or extraterritorial sanctions limiting the economic activities of third-state actors with “primary targets” ( Meyer 2009 , 906) blurs the line between involuntary participants and nonparticipants. Economic restrictions can result in multiple consequences with varying intensities depending on factors such as the type of sanction sender and the target, the scope and type of sanctions, and the relations between sanction senders, targets, and third-party states. Such variations show the need to review different types of sanction consequences and to understand the conditions under which they occur.

Economic Consequences of Sanctions

Research demonstrates that the intensity and probability of facing the economic impacts of sanctions vary across different actors. Targets may face consequences ranging from economic downfall to limited or no costs, while some sanctions may “strengthen” targets ( Park 2014 , 202–3). In contrast, sanction senders and third-party states tend not to experience economic effects above minor or medium levels, while only minor impacts were witnessed on the system level.

Evaluations of the overall economic effects of sanctions on targets focus on detecting changes (after sanction imposition) in the gross domestic product (GDP), the gross national product (GNP) ( Drezner 2000 , 90–91), or GDP growth rates ( Neuenkirch and Neumeier 2015 ). However, such cumulative results of shrinking trade and other economic disturbances caused by sanctions vary across cases. While the United States’ selective sanctions against China had no “significant adverse effect” on its economy ( Yang et al. 2004 ), the 2011–2014 sanctions against Iran decreased Iran's GDP by 17 percent ( Gharehgozli 2017 ); comprehensive UN sanctions devastated Iraq's economy. Investigating such differences, studies show that comprehensive UN sanctions have a higher negative effect on targets’ GDP than UN sanctions in general ( Neuenkirch and Neumeier 2015 ). Similarly, multilateral UN sanctions tend to have stronger effects on the target's GDP growth than unilateral US sanctions ( Neuenkirch and Neumeier 2015 ), while higher cooperation between the senders of multilateral sanctions is likely to increase targets’ costs ( Drezner 2000 ). However, as EU sanctions are found to be less effective than those imposed by the UN ( Besedeš, Goldbach, and Nitsch 2017 ), there is a need to differentiate between different multilateral sanctions. Moreover, considering the degree of economic power (dis)parity and dependence between targets and senders may help explain the differences in targets’ costs. However, analyzing such costs is tricky due to the limitations of available datasets, which is discussed in the following section.

There are contradictory findings on the impact of sanctions on foreign direct investment (FDI), which may shrink due to the expectations of higher risks and lower profits for investors caused by trade or investment restrictions. While case studies show a decrease of foreign investment inflows in the case of sanctions against China ( Yang et al. 2004 ) and Russia ( Gurvich and Prilepskiy 2015 ), a recent large- N study suggests that economic sanctions are unlikely to harm targets’ international trade or foreign direct or portfolio investment, irrespective of the types of sanctions ( Shin, Choi, and Luo 2015 ). Earlier studies also show that FDI from the United States decreases during sanction threats but returns to initial levels after sanction imposition ( Biglaiser and Lektzian 2011 ). FDI from other states may substitute for lost investments from the sender ( Lektzian and Biglaiser 2013 ). However, the reported lack of any sanction impact ( Shin, Choi, and Luo 2015 ), contradicting the observations in case studies, is surprising. This contradiction could result from the operationalizations used by Shin, Choi, and Luo (2015) . They analyzed net trade (percentage of exports to imports) and net FDI inflows (difference between inflows and outflows), which could hide the balancing effects of decreasing FDI outflows and lower imports due to countersanctions and decreasing purchasing power. Thus, such contradictions may indicate the need to reevaluate the categorizations and operationalizations used in quantitative studies and to look at case studies to understand the dynamics behind different indicators.

There is more agreement on the question of the financial impacts of sanctions on targeted states. Sanctions decrease financial flows between sanctions senders and targets ( Besedeš, Goldbach, and Nitsch 2017 ). They may also lead to lower availability of international financing, as was experienced by Russia witnessing “institutional illiquidity,” “limited capital market access,” increased “state funding” ( Pak and Kretzschmar 2016 , 577), and “decoupling” of the local stock market from the global one ( Castagneto-Gissey and Nivorozhkin 2016 , 82). Decreasing access to financing, and possible overall economic shocks, increases the likelihood of banking crises (especially under financial and costlier sanctions) ( Hatipoglu and Peksen 2018 ). Costlier and multilateral sanctions have bigger effects on financial instability and currency crises due to the possibility of “speculative attacks” based on sanction-related political risks, while the type of sanctioned sector can determine the gravity of such outcomes ( Peksen and Son 2015 , 456). Sanction-related country risks and targeted restrictions could lead to higher volatility in stock indices in Russia ( Ankudinov, Ibragimov, and Lebedev 2017 ), while unanticipated sanctions contributed to higher currency volatility ( Dreger et al. 2016 ). While such research suggests that impacts on the targets’ financial sector depend on multiple characteristics of the sanctions, there is yet little knowledge on which states are more likely to experience such costs and how sanction threats influence financial stability.

Economic sanctions can also impact nonsanctioned sectors due to the reduced demand for intermediary goods, as well as to lower incomes and employment ( Khan 1988 , 135–39). Impacts on the target's welfare and employment, however, depend on the targets’ economic characteristics (such as the price elasticity of labor and goods markets) ( Black and Cooper 1987 ). Targeted states may experience negative impacts in “tourism, communications, aid, transfer of technology” ( Doxey 1980 , 487). Even in the case of a successful adjustment to sanctions, targets are likely to have additional logistical costs, higher “risk premiums,” and a slowdown in “long-run development” ( van Bergeijk 1995 , 450); they may end up buying commodities via third parties or of lower quality ( Amuzegar 1997 , 32) and selling products at lower prices ( Haidar 2017 ). Moreover, economic sanctions may continue to affect a target's exports even after sanctions are lifted, which may be related to the “sunk costs” of the affected trade relationships ( Evenett 2002 , 558, 572). However, as often such findings are based on case studies of major sanction episodes, further quantitative or comparative studies could help understand the likelihood and duration of such impacts. Indeed, a study on the long-term effects of sanctions shows that sanctions lead to protectionism because target's elites competing with imports may be strengthened by sanction and demand market protection after the sanctions end ( Pond 2015 , 16–17).

Nevertheless, some sanctions may unintentionally benefit targets by causing “siege morality” and mobilizing people, thereby contributing to the growth of domestic productive sectors (as reportedly happened in Iran) ( Amuzegar 1997 , 35) or possibly stimulating industrialization (Zimbabwe) ( Watanabe 1987 , 537). Alternatively, the pre-2014 sanctions on North Korea “deepen[ed]” business relations between Korean and Chinese companies and made their interactions more efficient ( Park 2014 , 210). Given that such evidence comes from case studies, there is a need for large- N studies to understand whether such consequences are systematic or specific to certain targets or senders.

Sanction senders themselves incur economic costs as they restrict their own economic transactions by imposing sanctions; such costs may be even necessary as they signal the sender's commitment to the demands ( Lektzian and Sprecher 2007 , 416). However, early studies assumed that due to senders’ capacity to adjust these costs, they are likely to be short term ( Bayard, Pelzman, and Perezlopez 1983 , 76) and rather small, especially in cases of unilateral sanctions for economies as large as the United States ( Farmer 2000 ). Even with adjustments and depending on the type and scope of sanctions, the type of target, and the presence of international support, senders may face some costs (such as trading with less preferable markets, sectoral disruptions, competition with other markets, “adjusting to new trade partners,” and possible countersanctions) ( Farmer 2000 ).

Later studies show that dependent on the type of sanctions, even the United States experiences sanction impacts (such as a decreasing volume of trade ( Hufbauer et al. 1997 ) and decreasing financial flows [in the case of financial sanctions] ( Besedeš, Goldbach, and Nitsch 2017 ) between senders and targets). Such impacts are related to the interdependent nature of trade relations: to restrict trade of a target, a sender needs to restrict its own interactions with the target. Moreover, when the target is a large economy, senders may face higher costs: this happened when the United States’ sanctions against China caused additional costs for United States’ consumers and increased the United States’ trade deficit while benefiting its rivals in some areas ( Yang et al. 2004 , 1078). Moreover, lost exports and a reduction in export-related highly paid jobs may reduce average wages ( Hufbauer et al. 1997 ). Some targets may impact senders by countermeasures ( Doxey 1980 , 487; Farmer 2000 ), as exemplified by Russia's countersanctions against the EU, which decreased the Baltic states’ GDP by 0.4–0.8 percent ( Veebel and Markus 2018 , 15–16). However, how the characteristics of senders and their relations with other states influence senders’ costs needs investigation.

Sanction costs vary between sanction senders, even within the same sanctioning state; it is often private actors who incur the sanction costs ( Botterill and McNaughton 2008 ). For example, EU sanctions against Russia and Russia's countersanctions have been found to cause a decline in agricultural sectors (varying across the EU), while the chemical sectors of Malta and Lithuania increased their exports to Russia ( Giumelli 2017 , 1077). Similarly, while some of a sender state's businesses can temporally disinvest from the targeted economies ( Biglaiser and Lektzian 2011 ) or lose access to the targets’ market, others may circumvent sanctions, investing in sanction-busting or not participating in sanctions states in order to continue trading with the target ( Barry and Kleinberg 2015 ). Financial institutions in sanctioning states also experience the rising costs of compliance with new procedures necessary to adjust to restrictions, particularly in selective financial sanctions ( Arnold 2016 , 89). Such institutions bear the costs related to “de-risking” (quitting some activities due to high risks) while limiting regulated banking activity, which can increase unregulated financial activity ( Arnold 2016 , 91). Such “evasive economic activity” was reported on the Chinese borders as a result of the sanctions imposed on North Korea ( Lee and Gray 2017 , 424–26). The remaining questions are which sanctioning states and sectors are more likely to experience the costs of sanctions and when private actors tend to adjust to or circumvent sanctions. Considering the use of circumvention or secondary sanctions may help better understand different sanction costs for senders.

Third-party states also incur the economic costs of sanctions. They can influence sanction costs for senders and targets, and they depend on these states’ actions. Involuntary participants of UN sanctions, which require the compliance of all member states, may face significant costs if they depend on their economic relations with the target. Although such states may ask for compensation or exemption from imposing sanctions ( Doxey 1996a ), the effectiveness of such cost-mitigating measures may be limited. Sanction impacts may vary depending on third-party states’ dependence on the targeted economy, their ability to adjust, the flexibility of the related markets, as well as sanction costs for targets. Targets’ land neighbors may face higher costs of UN sanctions because of decreased imports and exports, adjustment costs to new markets, and “increased transportation costs and trade disruptions” ( Slavov 2007 , 1722). Likewise, the industries of states with close relations to both senders and targets may be harmed (e.g., having production facilities in a targeted state while selling their products to the sender) ( Yang et al. 2004 ). Partners of the targeted states may lose their own trade revenues when sanctions reduce the economic activity of the target ( Yang et al. 2009 , 1225), as was predicted for Greece or Turkey in 2000 and 2005 with a model simulating the effects of multilateral oil sanctions against Iraq ( Canes 2000 , 142–43). In contrast, targets’ rivals may even benefit, as happened when oil exporters enjoyed additional demand during sanctions against Iraq ( Canes 2000 , 143).

Nonmandatory sanctions may also benefit third-party states when a target shifts its trade to their markets ( Haidar 2017 ). This was the case as Iran refocused trade from Europe to Asia ( Esfahani and Rasoulinezhad 2017 ). Similarly, among sanction senders, the first states that lift sanctions may benefit from being the initial party to enter the targeted state's market ( Freeman 1993 ). Additionally, states that are likely to continue trade with a target under sanctions may benefit from higher investment inflows from the sender's firms (who are trying to overcome the sanctions) ( Barry and Kleinberg 2015 ). Moreover, the target's allies, dependent on their trade with targets, are likely to increase trade under sanctions ( Early 2012 , 568), and even a sender's allies may increase trade with the target due to their domestic firms’ preferences ( Early 2009 ). Considering that in some cases the senders’ allies (at least in short term) support sanction senders ( Yang et al. 2009 ) and that secondary sanctions were found to cause lasting EU support of United States’ sanctions on Iran ( Lohmann 2016 ), future studies should analyze secondary sanctions as well as allies’ dependencies on senders to understand when such support may occur.

The literature proposes that economic sanctions may also have some system-level effects. Early studies argued that sanctions, especially those imposed on important economies, could lead to “disruption of trade and investment, blocking of channels of exchange; emphasis on self-sufficiency; loss of certainty; loss of confidence” ( Doxey 1980 , 488); they could cause spillover effects and uncertainty about a partner's ability to trade, and lower the efficacy of international markets ( van Bergeijk 1995 , 451–52). Though no major sanction-induced disruption has yet occurred, Jones and Whitworth (2014) argue that sanctions may cause divisions in the global financial infrastructure and less effective financial markets, exemplified by Russia and China's attempts to create alternatives to the society for worldwide interbank financial telecommunication (SWIFT) system (from which Iran was banned by sanctions) ( Arnold 2016 , 92). Sanctions affecting exporters or importers representing a large share of the market may affect flows and prices of global goods, as when sanctions on Iraq increased oil prices by about 2 to 3 percent ( Canes 2000 , 143).

To sum, research suggests that while multilateral and comprehensive sanctions are likely to be costlier for targets, these costlier sanctions are also likely to be more damaging for economically close third-party states. However, while there exists some agreement on the economic effects of sanctions on targets, evidence of such costs for senders and third-party states is mostly limited to those case studies that focus on major sanction episodes (which may lead to biased conclusions). Similarly, use of different datasets, different controlling variables, and measurements makes it difficult to compare studies with diverging findings. An in-depth investigation of the mechanisms behind the sanction impacts may help better understand how sanctions work and contribute to more sophisticated analyses especially on the areas where present scholarship presents conflicting findings. Future research on sanction costs may also account for the interconnectedness between economic costs for different actors and their interactions.

Political Consequences of Sanctions

The political consequences of sanctions for senders or third-party states are either minor or absent. In contrast, targeted regimes and their populations may experience multiple political consequences, such as weakening some regimes and strengthening others. This section discusses studies on the likelihood of different actors to face political impacts of sanctions.

Some economic sanctions are explicitly aimed to inflict political costs on targets (to challenge targeted regimes), while other sanctions may have inadvertent political effects. Quantitative studies show that sanctions destabilize targeted regimes, increasing the probability of a leadership change ( Marinov 2005 ), and escalate political “antigovernmental activity” due to the sanction-related “economic hardship” suffered by the population ( Allen 2008 , 916) (though both political effects are more likely in democracies than in more autocratic states). A recent study shows that sanction threats, types of sanctions, and their senders are important for the domestic politics of targets, and threats of especially multilateral sanctions increase political activity in targeted states due to their signaling effect of outside support to opposition ( Grauvogel, Licht, and von Soest 2017 , 93). 2 As Marinov (2005) also proposed that threats could be even more destabilizing than imposed sanctions, future studies focusing on sanction threats in relation to governmental change are needed.

Targets’ regime types may influence the consequences of different sanctions. Brooks (2002) proposed that comprehensive sanctions influencing voters are more likely to create political costs for democratic regimes, whereas sanctions targeting specific elites are costlier for authoritarian regimes depending on narrower support bases. Even among authoritarian regimes, there are differences in the political effects of sanctions. Sanctioned theocratic regimes are shown to strengthen themselves using religious rhetoric ( Naghavi and Pignataro 2015 ). Personalist regimes are argued to be less likely to comply with liberalization demands than “more factionalist” military states, as divided elites are more likely to “capitulate” to external demands while united regimes tend to “fight to the end” ( Walldorf 2014 , 645). Perhaps in connection with this observation, personalist regimes are less likely to survive sanctions than military or single-party regimes, though economic power and oil resources may reduce such destabilization risks ( Escribà-Folch and Wright 2010 ). While the research could be enriched by comparing different types of sanctions, these studies demonstrate the importance of analyzing the internal dynamics within targeted states. Developing “social conflict analysis of sanctions,” Jones (2015 , 38) argues that their political impacts indeed depend on the political struggles within the targeted states that may lead to different outcomes.

The reactions of targeted governments in response to sanctions also diverge. North Korean leaders, during sixty years of sanctions, adopted reform-oriented rhetoric in response to negative sanctions (to appease the population) and more conflictual stances in response to positive sanctions ( Kim 2014 ). Targeted leaders trying to minimize the political costs of sanctions may attempt to create a “rallying-around-the-flag” effect by emphasizing identities and “embattled sovereignty” ( Jaeger 2016 , 966); they may also appeal to popular emotions in an attempt to increase leadership's resilience to sanctions ( Galtung 1967 , 404, 411). A large- N study evaluating the rallying-around-the-flag effect argues that sanctions may strengthen authoritarian regimes resisting democratization if the society sees them as legitimate and is weakly connected to the sanction senders ( Grauvogel and von Soest 2014 , 645–46).

Sanctions may strengthen targeted regimes due to an incumbent's response to limit “public goods” and weaken possible “challengers” ( Oechslin 2014 , 25), while a deteriorating targeted economy weakens civil society and the “middle and lower classes” ( Fathollah-Nejad 2014 , 62). While especially comprehensive sanctions are known to negatively influence democratic freedoms ( Peksen and Drury 2010 ), purposefully “democratic sanctions” correlate with “increasing levels of democracy” in targeted states ( von Soest and Wahman 2015 , 972). Von Soest and Wahman's (2015) findings suggest the need to differentiate between the purposes of sanctions because they may influence sanction designs. The purposes and designs of sanctions may in turn cause different reactions from targeted leaders and influence their survival chances differently. Moreover, because the studies use different datasets covering different periods (1972–2000 and 1990–2010, respectively), some differences in their observations could relate to the evolving sanction designs and changing political contexts after the end of the Cold War.

While sanctions often aim to improve human rights records, they may fail to do so, particularly if they are less costly for targeted regimes than abandoning oppression ( Morgan and Schwebach 1995 ) or the costs of compliance. A study by Drury and Li (2006) suggests that the United States’ threats of sanctions could lead to less protection of human rights in China due to the possible audience costs of China's compliance with the external demands. A large- N study by Wood (2008 , 509) concluded that sanctions (especially multilateral) tend to increase repression used by targeted regimes to mute any domestic dissent. For similar reasons, human rights for physical integrity can deteriorate under extensive, multilateral, and prolonged sanctions ( Peksen 2009 ). “Extensive and high-cost sanctions” are also especially likely to weaken property rights in targeted countries where governments may resort to “predatory” tactics to decrease their economic woes ( Peksen 2017 , 225). Finally, even targeted UN sanctions may worsen human rights or make a human rights situation less likely to improve ( Carneiro and Apolinário 2016 ). Such research demonstrates that especially comprehensive and multilateral sanctions consistently intensify political oppression and damage human rights in targeted states.

Looking at alternative intervening factors, Escriba-Folch (2012) proposes that repression is most likely to increase under personalist regimes with severe budget constraints; among the less budgetary constrained regimes, single-party rulers tend to subsidize their own supporters, while militarist regimes increase military spending ( Escriba-Folch 2012 , 705). Increased military spending is proposed by McDonald III and Vincent (2016) as a means used by militarist regimes to offset a weakened economy. Thus, these studies demonstrate the importance of narrowing the typologies of targeted states and accounting for their domestic constraints.

Economic sanctions are found to worsen women's rights, especially in countries with a lower GDP per capita and under longer and costlier sanctions; such impacts are less serious under “humanitarian sanctions” ( Drury and Peksen 2012 , 475–83). Analyzing sanctions against Iraq, Buck, Gallant, and Nossal (1998 , 81–82) demonstrate that sanctions have gendered impacts; they add an additional burden for women, who provide housekeeping and childcare under crisis conditions (with fewer income opportunities), experience a “decline in dowry wealth,” and have less independence within their families. Sanctions (especially multilateral and/or extensive) also undermine media openness as targeted governments may try to censor criticizing the media, while the media may have less funding resources within a weakening economy ( Peksen 2010 , 459). Thus, as less resources are available to nongovernmental actors, and governments try to further suppress domestic dissent, sanctions often result in the deterioration of civil freedoms.

Sanctions may violate human rights when humanitarian programs fail to prevent sanction-inflicted human suffering ( Herring 2002 , 56). Sanctions may also violate a person's human rights by targeting individuals without a “fair hearing” or the possibility of an appeal against UN sanctions listings ( Elliott 2009 , 95). Erroneous listings may harm the targeted individual's economic situation and reputation ( Biersteker 2010 , 103; Eriksson 2016 ). There has been little discussion of these issues and research into the “social and collective impacts of individual sanctions” is yet to develop ( Tourinho 2015 , 1412).

Economic sanctions may also influence conflicts and security in targeted states. While some argue sanctions may end conflicts, others conclude that this is due to the combination of sanctions and military interventions ( Pape 1997 ; Eriksson and Wallensteen 2015 , 1395). While sanctions are associated with shorter civil conflicts ( Escribà-Folch 2010 ), they are found to increase the ethnic discrimination ( Peksen 2016 ) that results from unequal suffering from sanction costs, to increase ethnic violence ( Lv and Xu 2017 ) and civil conflict intensity (unless they limit the military capacity of the targeted governments) ( Hultman and Peksen 2017 ). Although shortening civil conflicts and increasing conflict intensity seems contradictory, Escribà-Folch (2010) shows that sanctions imposed outside of international organizations are likely to contribute to military victories; quicker military victories may correspond to increased conflict intensities. If international organization (IO)-imposed sanctions may help resolve conflicts either by presenting a possible enforcer of negotiated peace or by ensuring senders’ commitment ( Escribà-Folch 2010 ), one could analyze whether such sanctions also reduce conflict intensity.

Targeted states may also witness an increase in international terrorism events ( Choi and Luo 2013 ) because terrorist groups may become stronger when the states fighting them are sanctioned; in contrast, such groups may weaken when the states providing them “sanctuaries” are targeted by sanctions ( McLean et al. 2016 , 378). Thus, the latter study shows the importance of exploring the nature of relations between states and nonstate actors to understand sanction effects.

The international political effects of sanctions also diverge. Some sanctions may bring the targeted state new allies instead of isolating it ( Amuzegar 1997 , 35). Within existing international disputes, stronger sanctions might escalate war by fostering weapon trade between targets and sanction busters ( Garoupa and Gata 2002 ). However, large- N studies show that especially unilateral sanctions signal to third-party states international disapproval and weakening of the target and, therefore, increase the probability of military action against targeted states by others by about 50 percent ( Peterson and Drury 2011 , 595–96). Moreover, to minimize sanction costs, senders are more likely to use violence against targets ( Lektzian and Sprecher 2007 ). The conditions under which sanctions bring targets new allies or increase the likelihood of military actions against targets are yet to be understood in relation to the type of sanctions and sanction senders. As some sanctions aim to prevent conflicts or support peacebuilding, more research (especially with a focus on smart sanctions) is needed in these areas ( Eriksson and Wallensteen 2015 ).

Similar to targeted states, some groups within sanction senders may benefit from sanctions ( Kaempfer and Lowenberg 1988 ); the broader political consequences for sanction-imposing governments are less clear. While Whang (2011) shows that the use of sanctions by the United States’ presidents is associated with higher domestic support, Webb (2018 , 505–6), analyzes a broader set of sanctions (including trade-related sanctions) to find that sanctions correspond to a “small decrease in presidential approval” related to dissatisfaction with economic costs for senders. While controlling for political scandals, crises, or wars, the latter study does not explore the differences between public response to unilateral and multilateral sanctions. Webb (2018 , 506) acknowledges the possibility of positive effects, but their enabling conditions are unclear, and analyzing the differences between these conflicting studies could help understand such conditions.

Experimental studies show that public support for sanctions may depend on perceptions of sanction effectiveness and harm for targeted populations ( McLean and Roblyer 2017 ) or expectations about the long-term effects of sanctions ( Heinrich, Kobayashi, and Peterson 2017 ); however, the effects of such factors on attitudes toward sanctioning governments is not known. Such insights can be used to investigate actual public support for sanctions.

Besides the effects on domestic politics, sanctions may worsen relations between senders and targets ( Fathollah-Nejad 2014 ), even if sanctions were intended to increase cooperation. The international image of a sanction-threatening state may be weakened if the state fails to impose sanctions after making threats ( Peterson 2013 ), while successful and failed sanctions may sometimes alienate even the sender's allies ( Hufbauer et al. 2009 , 112). Academic research on the symbolic impacts of sanctions is still too limited and there is no systematic explanation of which sanctions influence international attitudes toward sanction senders and how.

The existing research on the alignment of third parties with senders or targets, however, shows that if a targeted state has high political importance (as in case of EU sanctions on Russia), alignment with the sender by third states is less probable and lack of such alignment may question the “normative” authority of the EU ( Hellquist 2016 , 1015). Target and third states’ relations can also deteriorate when third states, dependent on trade with targets, suffer losses ( Hellquist 2016 ). This shows that the political effects are not limited to targets or senders or their relations, but include third states, and that their relationships are highly interdependent.

The few additional studies on third-party states show that neighbors of targets of human rights-related sanctions ( Carneiro 2014 , 210) and third-party states, perceiving themselves as “similar” to the target, are likely to improve their own human rights records being deterred by such sanctions ( Peterson 2014 , 161). In contrast, if sanctions are threatened but not imposed, third-party states may become more likely to resist senders’ future demands, especially in similar contexts ( Peterson 2013 , 679). While such research shows that sanctions improve human rights in third-party states, one could also examine whether the deterrent effects of sanctions are dependent on their cost. Given that third-party states may be harmed by secondary sanctions or spillovers from targets, researchers could analyze the political consequences of such secondary risks.

On a systemic level, such deterrence of third-party states from violating norms or from cooperating with violators may be seen to strengthen human rights norms ( Carneiro 2014 ; Peterson 2014 ) or “international trade regimes” in goods like diamonds ( Eriksson 2016 , 201). Anti-proliferation sanctions are also argued to prevent third-party states’ proliferation, irrespective of targets’ persistence ( Miller 2014 ), even if such sanctions may reinforce a target's perception of security threats and “push” the target toward proliferation ( Paul 1996 , 465; Miyagiwa and Ohno 2015 ). However, it is unclear which of the consequences has a stronger effect on the nonproliferation regime. Finally, the UN's legitimacy and “normative order” is arguably damaged by problems with sanctioning individuals as discussed above ( Eriksson 2016 , 201), though the impacts are difficult to evaluate.

While research shows that targets are by far the most likely actor to experience the political costs of sanctions, the intensity of such impacts varies even for targets, often depending on the internal dynamics of the targeted states and their relations with other countries. The findings of the political effects on senders and third-party states similarly suggest their contingency on sanctions effects for targets. Still, further theorizing of the processes behind political effects of economic sanctions for different actors is necessary. Similarly, additional analysis of secondary sanctions is needed to understand effects of such measures on third-party states. Finally, as studies on sanction senders often focus on the United States, these processes in different contexts remain understudied.

Humanitarian and Other Consequences

While the effects of sanctions on sanction senders and third-party states are mostly limited to economic and political impacts, the states targeted by the costliest sanctions may also face humanitarian consequences. For example, due to worsened economic conditions and failing services, Iraq experienced a lack of drinking water, proper sewage systems, fuel, and wood as well as an increase in the spread of disease ( Buck, Gallant, and Nossal 1998 ) and mortality ( Mack and Khan 2000 , 284). Iran and Syria suffered a decline in the availability of food and medicines ( Moret 2015 , 130). Even medicines excluded from sanctions may become less available due to higher prices, problems with transportation and funding, or companies’ unwillingness to engage in the complicated process of selling even permitted goods to targets ( Setayesh and Mackey 2016 , 5–6), as witnessed in Iran ( Shahabi et al. 2015 ; Karimi and Haghpanah 2015 ). Because such impacts are (mostly) demonstrated in case studies, quantitative research could help identify the conditions determining such effects.

One of the quantitative analyses of sanctions’ effects on public health shows that sanctions may “reduce immunization rates and government spending on health care,” especially during military conflicts ( Allen and Lektzian 2013 , 133). Among the later quantitative studies in this area, McLean and Whang (2019) show that as sanctions tend to decrease a target's revenues, social spending or expenditures in natural disaster prevention also decreases that may increase a country's costs in the case of a disaster. Gutmann, Neuenkirch, and Neumeier (2020) demonstrate that sanctions tend to decrease life expectancy in targeted states and especially influence women's life expectancy in the first years after sanction imposition. Such an effect is particularly evident in countries with a below average domestic political environment and may be caused by increased child mortality, the unmitigated spread of diseases, and a decrease in health-related expenditure ( Gutmann, Neuenkirch, and Neumeier 2020 ). Child mortality tends to increase under costlier sanctions, as well as under those imposed by the United States, due to a population's worsening welfare and lack of “basic needs” and healthcare ( Peksen 2011 ). Such an effect may also occur due to decreased incomes, limited maternal access to health services, and an escalation in the conflict (as happened in case of the Democratic Republic of Congo) ( Parker, Foltz, and Elsea 2016 ).

Sanction threats may increase corruption by creating expectations of increased rivalry for resources, especially in states where corruption is already frequent ( Balanov 2017 ). Similarly, reported to increase corruption, UN-targeted sanctions are also associated with higher criminality rates in more than half of the cases ( Eriksson 2016 , 202). Although earlier criminalizing effects were reported for the 1992–1995 sanctions against Yugoslavia ( Andreas 2010 ), it is unclear when and why such effects occur. Sanctions can also increase inequality ( Cooper 1989 ), especially if they are prolonged and if targeted states have low education levels and a lack of capital investment (exacerbating the exploitation of low-paid labor) ( Afesorgbor and Mahadevan 2016 , 5). Likewise, poverty gaps are found to increase under sanctions, particularly with more severe and multilateral sanctions, which may be caused by a weakening economy, an undersupply of goods and services, or uneven resource reallocation under sanctions ( Neuenkirch and Neumeier 2016 , 111,117). Regional inequalities may also widen, as happened in North Korea where regional capacities to overcome sanctions depended on the proximity to borders ( Lee and Gray 2017 ). Finally, trade sanctions are reported to increase child labor due to falling household incomes, although this may be mitigated by greater access to credit ( Jafarey and Lahiri 2002 ); sanctions specifically directed against goods produced by child labor do not produce the desired outcome ( Basu, Chau, and Grote 2006 ).

Although the humanitarian costs of comprehensive sanctions have led to the design of targeted sanctions, targeted UN sanctions are found to have humanitarian consequences in 44 percent of cases ( Eriksson 2016 ). Such consequences are more probable when sanctions have economic and political, or only economic, impacts ( Elliott 2016 , 183–84), as larger economic costs act as an intermediate mechanism leading to the humanitarian costs of sanctions. An analysis of United States’ sanctions imposed since 2000 shows that they reduced the human development index of targeted countries and increased corruption ( Rosenberg et al. 2016 , 19). Thus, there is still a need to identify whether factors like the specific design of sanctions, number of senders, or target types influence such outcomes.

While the humanitarian consequences for third-party states (or on the system-level) have not been studied, media reports on increasing refugee flows to targets’ neighbors 3 suggest the need to analyze such impacts for third-party states. The unexplored effects of sanctions on migration ( Weiss 1999 , 505), mental health, environment ( Bessler, Garfield, and Hugh 2004 , 82–85), and many other variables require further research. Moreover, as studies on humanitarian costs of sanctions often focus on specific cases, quantitative studies and analyses of the mechanisms behind such effects could help understand their determinants. Acknowledging that many consequences have yet to be uncovered, we hope that this review summarize the general dimensions of the research.

The following section summarizes some limitations common to sanction literature. We acknowledge that the issues highlighted in this section are inevitably selective and they neither include all shortcomings of the scholarship nor diminish its incredible value.

Thematic Issues

One of the main weaknesses of the research on sanction consequences is that it is divided into almost incommunicado compartments along several lines. Such fragmentation limits scientific discussion within each “compartment” of the literature and prevents a broader discussion of this topic. The most persistent divide within the literature focuses on the actors or entities influenced by economic sanctions. The lack of communication between works focusing on different actors inhibits a full understanding of the impacts on each actor. This fragmentation may be one of the factors behind the inconsistent or even contradictory results on economic consequences for senders and targets, as the review in this paper has shown.

Estimating sanction costs for targets without considering the types of senders, their motivations, the international and domestic constraints of such decisions, or senders’ abilities to adjust their own economic interactions may lead to misleading findings. For example, relatively similar sanctions imposed on a single target may have different consequences due to different motivations and constraints of sanction senders. Connolly (2018 , 58) argues that while Japan imposed multiple restrictions on individuals and firms in Russia, sanctions were aimed to “signal” its commitment to Western allies rather than to convey a message to Russian decision-makers. Different from the United States and the EU, Japan spared the Russian energy sector; this could have provided a better bargaining position for Japan as an importer of energy resources and a possible exporter of energy-related technologies ( Connolly 2018 , 67). Studying the economic consequences of the same sanction types, without accounting for sender-related characteristics and motivations, may lead to different conclusions.

Another problem, especially within the “compartment” of consequences for sanction targets, is that such research typically focuses on states. As Peksen (2019 , 642) highlights, sanction effectiveness literature emphasizes the “state-centric approach” but neglects the increasing use of sanctions on “nonstate actors” (such as terrorist or illicit groups or particular individuals). Similar concerns are valid for the sanction consequences literature. Some studies about the impact on targeted individuals exist, yet, the broader impact of such targeting is understudied ( Tourinho 2015 , 1412). While the latest Targeted Sanctions Consortium's dataset includes variables identifying the specific entities targeted by sanctions, further research on the wider consequences of such sanctions is needed. Besides the lack of dialogue between studies on different influenced actors, the lack of attention to the different types of targets, their costs, and the related externalities is also critical.

Focusing on the impacts of sanctions on third states is also problematic. While third states are mostly seen as states not participating in sanctions, their roles may coincide with those of either sender or targets. In the case of UN sanctions, even a state opposing a sanction must comply with the UN Security Council resolution, thus becoming a sender. In the case of non-UN sanctions, a third-party state may face threats of secondary sanctions, being forced to either cut some economic ties with the targeted states (and thus implicitly join the sanction regime) or face repercussions of the sanction sender (taking the role of a secondary target). In such cases, considering the findings of research on sanction senders and targets could help analyze sanction consequences for third states. Following Peksen's (2019 , 8) argument that secondary sanctions can impact effectiveness and “sanction-busting” and, thus, should be more thoroughly studied in the sanction effectiveness literature, we suggest that such sanctions create even more questions in the sanction consequences literature. New research could focus on the difference in economic impacts of secondary sanctions on FDI flows across countries as contrasted with sanction episodes without secondary measures. One could also study the possibly increasing costs for private entities within sender states due to the decreasing chances of adjustments in the presence of secondary sanctions. Analyzing the possible political costs for third-party states in cases of compliance or noncompliance with secondary sanctions could also influence our understanding of the political effects of sanctions for third states. Thus, without accounting for secondary sanctions, deriving meaningful comparison between the consequences for different actors of different sanction regimes is also problematic.

Division of the literature along the lines of comprehensive, targeted, and smart sanctions presents another reason of fragmentation. While the difficulties to define and differentiate between such types also pose methodological difficulties as discussed in the next section, dividing literature into such types creates a problem on its own. While further learning on the consequences of smart sanctions is necessary, restricting large- N analyses to specific sanction types may prevent comparison between the impacts of different subtypes of sanctions and limit the degree of freedom in the research. An understanding of the differences in consequences of sanctions with different scopes is crucial to understand which designs are likely to minimize, if not to prevent, such humanitarian consequences of sanctions as increasing hunger or mortality.

While such categorizations may have theoretical and practical benefits for understanding different aspects of economic sanctions, the current state of research presents parts of research that rarely communicate. Using insights from different subareas (such as considering consequences for senders and their characteristics when analyzing sanction costs for targeted states) could greatly benefit the related research.

The literature's predominant focus on sanctions imposed by the United States is a significant thematic bias. The United States is the sanction initiator in “more than half” of sanction cases included in the widely used Threats and Imposition of Sanctions (TIES) dataset ( Webb 2018 , 495). Considering the scale of its economy, one may expect that most sanctions imposed by the United States are likely to harm the target much more than the United States itself, and often more than sanctions imposed by smaller economies. The impacts of multilateral sanctions may also potentially depend on whether the United States is among the senders. Certainly, there are studies which account for the regional sanction regimes such as those imposed by the European Union, Arab League, or African Union ( Borzyskowski and Portela 2016 ; Seeberg 2016 ). Moreover, a recent special issue, presenting seven studies on sanctions imposed by different regional organizations on their members, evaluates their influence on the “competing norms of democracy protection” ( Hellquist and Palestini 2020 , 2). Still, while it is not possible to account for every existing work on regional or non-US sanctions, the predominantly high frequency of US-oriented studies is likely to provide a skewed estimation of sanction consequences. Further focus on non-US unilateral or regional sanctions and types of sanction-sending states is necessary to produce more generalizable conclusions about sanction consequences.

Methodological Issues

Different methodological approaches used in sanction consequences research, albeit providing diversity, also contribute to fragmentation of the literature. Another important fragmentation in sanction consequences research is related to the methods used in different studies. While in-depth case studies identify multiple novel mechanisms behind sanction impacts and identify novel consequences faced by different actors, many of these insights are absent from the quantitative research, which uses large- N studies based on existing datasets. Lack of better communication between case studies and quantitative studies often hinders the possibility of improvement of the research. Moreover, methodologic divides create conflicting findings as exemplified by how foreign investment under sanctions is reported to decrease by a case study ( Gurvich and Prilepskiy 2015 ) but to remain unaffected by a quantitative analysis ( Shin, Choi, and Luo 2015 ). A lack of dialogue between the two approaches prevents an understanding of whether the contradictory results found in the different works are caused by the exceptional nature of a sanction case or different operationalization or measurements used in large- N studies.

Even between different quantitative studies there are conflicting findings, which may be due to different datasets or different controlling variables. Most quantitative studies use one of three available datasets: Hufbauer et al. (2009) a dataset by Hufbauer, Schott, Elliott, and Oegg (2009) (HSE/HSEO), threat and imposition of economic sanctions dataset (TIES) ( Morgan, Bapat, and Kobayashi 2014 ), and the latest, Targeted Sanction Consortium (TSC) ( Biersteker et al. 2018 ). The TSC dataset deals with the most recent cases and accounts for the changes in sanctioning regimes (dividing them into episodes), novel variables (such as goals) in terms of “signaling/stigmatizing,” and whether the sanction means to “coerce” substate actors as particular groups or terrorists. Although the dataset addresses Peksen's (2019 , 7–8) critique on the prevailing focus on state actors in the literature on sanctions and the lack of “time-varying sanction data” ( Peksen 2019 , 641), its restricted focus only on targeted UN sanctions leaves the limitations of larger datasets unresolved. While the most recent dataset developed by Felbermayr et al. (2020) also argues to provide a solution for the dynamic nature of sanctions, future studies are needed to estimate the effects of the newly available data.

Different coding in these datasets also makes the reproduction of earlier results more difficult ( Van Bergeijk and Siddiquee 2017 ; van Bergeijk 2019 , 6–7). For example, costs are estimated in US dollars in TIES ( Morgan, Bapat, and Kobayashi 2014 ), as an index in HSE dataset ( Hufbauer et al. 2009 ), and as various types of possible costs (including reputational costs) in TSC ( Targeted Sanctions Consortium 2014 ). Due to such differences in indicators, combining datasets to analyze longer periods or larger numbers of cases remains difficult.

Different operationalizations, definitions, or names of the same variables used in these studies make comparing different studies difficult. While comprehensive sanctions targeting the whole target's economy and “smart sanctions” restricting smaller parts of the economy are seemingly distinct, the scope of each sanction type varies, making such divides less clear. Comprehensive (or “extensive” ( Peksen and Drury 2010 , 249)) sanctions range from overall embargos to sanctions only on imports or exports. “Smart sanctions” are sometimes called “targeted” ( Gordon 2011 , 315) or “selective” sanctions and can have different designs and scopes, as exemplified by the targeted sanctions imposed against Russia by Japan in comparison with costlier and broader targeted sanctions imposed by the United States ( Connolly 2018 ). Some scholars alternatively divide “smart sanctions” into “targeted sanctions” aiming to influence individuals or entities and “selective sanctions” targeting “products or financial flows” ( Hufbauer et al. 2009 , 125). To add to this complexity, alternative sanction typologies related to the tools they employ can differ between those targeting aid, assets, finance, money, trade ( Kirshner 1997 , 41), or other factors. This differentiation is important as, for example, financial sanctions tend to impose higher costs on targets than other targeted sanctions ( Drezner 2015 , 757). As a better understanding of the differences in consequences of different sanctions is crucial, the use of more uniform and less ambiguous sanction typologies could increase the comparability of different studies.

The issue of including sanction threats into the analysis of sanctions poses a question of understanding the impacts of sanction threats and also may suggest a possible selection bias when one does not account for such threats. In fact, the imposition of sanctions after a lack of a target's response toward threats (at least when the sanction aims to inflict behavioral change) may show a higher resolve of the target to endure sanctions costs. A target's readiness to endure costs despite threats can, in turn, bias the results toward finding higher costs of sanctions. Thus, because sanction threats can influence which countries are sanctioned and how they respond, accounting for threats could reduce possible selection bias.

Theoretical Issues

Besides thematic and methodological divides, sanction consequences research lack a common theoretical framework behind such studies. Some scholars attempt to build game-theoretic models of sanctions ( Lacy and Niou 2004 ). Others apply different theories and approaches, such as the public choice approach ( Kaempfer and Lowenberg 1988 ) or the theory of conflict management ( Garoupa and Gata 2002 ). In addition, some studies analyze sanctions’ consequences within the scope of other theories, accounting for a context where sanctions and their consequences can take place (e.g., related to political protest and democratization). Many studies only implicitly rely on some broader theories while focusing on the relationship between the event of the sanctions and a specific impact of the sanctions but omitting alternative factors (e.g., other impacts of sanctions or relations with other actors), which can influence our understanding of the sanction outcome. Such additional theoretical fragmentation provides further difficulties for the dialogue between different studies, as they often employ approaches that are too different from one another.

While combining sanction scholarship with other disciplines provided a rich venue for research and understanding sanction consequences, the lack of a shared approach to understanding such consequences in different economic, political, and humanitarian (among others) spheres may lead to the relatively spontaneous use of some controlling variables and conflicting findings based on similar data. In the following section, we attempt to tackle this issue and present a shared approach for sanction consequences research.

A Common Approach to Sanction Consequences Research: Interdependence

While a single theory accounting for all of the sanction consequences literature would be impossible, a shared approach to frame sanction consequences, irrespective of the type of consequences or type of influenced actors, would help one avoid missing important variables. In this section, we discuss the possibility of a common approach to study sanction consequences within the larger topic of interdependence. We argue that such an approach could help bring together different fragments of the sanction consequences research.

Research on interdependence has its roots in the liberal and institutionalist theories suggesting that economic interdependence between states (increased economic relations between states) leads to more peaceful international relations, as states would not want to lose the benefits from trade by engaging in conflict. Interdependence “implies that the actions of states, and significant nonstate actors, will impose costs on other members of the system” and reflects a traditional understanding of the international system ( Keohane and Nye 1987 , 730). In contrast, an alternative ideal type of interdependence is “complex interdependence,” under which states have “multiple channels of contact,” do not use military force against each other, and “there is no hierarchy of issues” ( Keohane and Nye 1987 , 30–31, with reference to Keohane and Nye (1977)). However, while this theorizing on interdependence acknowledges multiple states, it is mostly limited to bilateral relations ( Wagner 1988 ). A rare study that tried to apply the classic liberal definition of interdependence to sanctions could not find a direct link between sanction initiation and level of interdependence ( Silva and Selden 2019 ).

The practice of economic sanctions is only possible in the presence of economic interactions between states and some sort of economic interdependence. Different kinds of interdependence may influence who can impose sanctions and how such sanctions will work. When considering the link between the fragmented literature on sanction consequences, we argue that the research on the impacts of sanctions on different actors is connected by the interdependent nature of the world political and economic structure. None of the actors influenced by sanctions is fully independent from the others and sanctions’ impacts on targets often influence other actors. Similarly, the nature of the targeted state (the connectedness or dependency of its economy to others and the volume of its markets) may influence how sanctions would affect different actors.

We propose that accounting for such interdependent context of sanctions is necessary to better understand sanction consequences. We argue this task can be achieved by studying the framework of economic networks in which different states function. Some earlier works also applied the social network approach to understand economic sanctions. Cranmer, Heinrich, and Desmarais (2014) and Dorff and Minhas (2017) see the sanctioning process as a network and analyze the sanction network dynamics between different senders and targets. However, these studies do not account for the contextual networks of economic relations within which sanctions are imposed. Peterson (2018) takes a broader approach, analyzing the trade network between different states. He evaluates the effect of states’ positions within the network (accounting for trade relations of targets and their counterparts) on sanction initiation and the effectiveness of sanction threats. Because not all sanctions target overall trade, focusing on such broader trade network may be less applicable to financial or other targeted sanctions.

Also focusing on the power derived from states’ positions within different exchange networks (such as financial, informational, or trade systems), Farell and Newman (2019) analyze states’ capacity to coerce others. They propose that states with central positions (hubs) in a network with hierarchical structures can control the network by monitoring it and expelling others from this network and, thus, may weaponize asymmetric interdependence. However, the authors focus only on coercive capacity of the central states in the systems and limit application of such approach to some hierarchical networks.

This paper suggests integrating the network approaches and applying them to sanction consequences research. We propose considering the narrower economic networks, within which sanctions are applied (which are more applicable for targeted sanctions), and the impacts of different state positions within the networks on sanction effects for different actors. Applying the idea of network-based interdependence to the context of sanction consequences can directly point to the often-overlooked factors that influence such consequences. We propose that it can provide one insightful way of approaching and understanding otherwise fragmented and often contradictory insights from the sanction consequences scholarship. We argue that the idea of a networked interdependence can bring the existing sanction scholarship together and provide answers to many of the limitations of the literature on sanction consequences. Some of such answers are summarized in the table 1 .

Some promises of the networked interdependence approach

Problematic issueNetwork approach-based answer
research fragmentation according to the affected actors.Consideration of the position within the network of all the actors (e.g.: center, periphery, bridge, not connected, other categories; highly connected versus weakly connected)
United States as a unique, most frequent sanction sender.The United States may not be a unique case but an instance of a central and well-connected country to many networks. Such categorization would make it comparable to other central countries in smaller networks.
: different approaches used by quantitative and qualitative research.Network approach can be used for both qualitative case studies and quantitative research when such data may become available.
: different theories are used to explain research in different areas. No approach is used across the whole literature.The networked interdependence approach can be applied to studies of sanction impacts for different actors.
Problematic issueNetwork approach-based answer
research fragmentation according to the affected actors.Consideration of the position within the network of all the actors (e.g.: center, periphery, bridge, not connected, other categories; highly connected versus weakly connected)
United States as a unique, most frequent sanction sender.The United States may not be a unique case but an instance of a central and well-connected country to many networks. Such categorization would make it comparable to other central countries in smaller networks.
: different approaches used by quantitative and qualitative research.Network approach can be used for both qualitative case studies and quantitative research when such data may become available.
: different theories are used to explain research in different areas. No approach is used across the whole literature.The networked interdependence approach can be applied to studies of sanction impacts for different actors.

Because interdependence presupposes mutually influencing relations, any evaluation of sanction consequences might consider the place of the target within the related economic network (e.g., in the case of an oil export restricting sanction within the network of oil trade). Sanction consequences are likely to be determined by the position of the sanction sender within the same network and the nature of their relations with the target (symmetry or asymmetry—dependence). The position of other states within the network (all connected to a sender, a target, or a third state) can also influence sanction impacts, not only on senders and targets but also on third-party states. Moreover, it can shed light on the possibility of sanction-busting behavior or incompliance with secondary sanctions if countries are connected not only to the sanction sender, but also to other hubs (or even being a central point itself).

Studying the structure of the targeted network of economic relations may also help predict targets’ capacity to adjust to sanctions. The presence of alternative trade partners not bound to the sanction sender is likely to enable an easier adjustment for the target, as it will be able to shift its own trade relations toward other partners. Russia's attempt to shift some of its economic relations from Western markets to Asia exemplifies the tactic of moving across a less hierarchical network. Similarly, while the network of oil and gas trade is supposed to be nonhierarchical ( Farrell and Newman 2019 ), the difficulty of adjusting some transportation types (such as pipelines) can, in the short run, prevent any possibility of adjustment. Russia's current construction of alternative gas pipelines can illustrate a state strengthening its own position within a network by creating new connections and becoming a network hub itself.

Considering the existing research on sanction consequences and the limitations outlined above, an interdependence approach can help move forward by considering the following issues when conducting future research: Accounting for senders’ positions within economic networks and their relations to targets can bring together studies on sanction consequences for senders and targets and reconcile inconsistent observations as different costs faced by different senders. Similarly, considering the nature of the targeted network (a single-centered network of a monopoly importer–exporter or a multicentered network with relatively equal relations) can help predict the target's ability to adjust and minimize its own costs. The target's position within the economic network (its connectedness to other actors, its ability to create its own hub, and the presence of other nonconnected actors) may also shed light on the possibility of a target's adjustment and its potential to harm the sender via counter sanctions or due to prolonged sanctions.

The issue of secondary sanctions in the context of a hierarchical network can be addressed by looking at whether the network within which such secondary sanctions are imposed has more than one central state and whether that central (hub) state is the one imposing the sanction. The aim of such research would be to look into the consequences of secondary sanctions within different networks (centralized or dispersed) or whether a noncentral state in a network can credibly impose secondary sanctions.

Finally, the problem of US-centered research could be addressed by considering the position of the United States and other states within the related networks. In the cases of dispersed networks, where the United States’ position is like that of other states, one can expect comparability in sanction consequences. In contrast, the scope of sanction impacts is likely to be different between sanctions imposed by the United States (being in the center of the related economic network) and sanctions imposed by another state or international organization located on the periphery of such a network. However, in both cases, the question of consequences for senders and targets would also depend on the position of the target within the same network.

Besides the focus on the central nodes of economic networks, there is also great potential in looking into other aspects of network qualities as defined by social network theories. Considering that social networks by their nature are likely to be clustered ( Newman and Park 2003 ) and that such clusters are connected by a small number of nodes called “bridging nodes” or “bridges,” one can theorize that states acting as bridges in different economic networks can have influence within such networks, increasing their capabilities.

The importance of bridging countries in an economic network can be exemplified by the pipeline-based natural gas networks that are rigid due to the costliness and difficulties of constructing a pipeline. A central state may control its oil or gas exports via pipelines and have multiple buyers on the ends of those pipelines, but some transit countries may also hold an influential position between the exporters and importers or be a “bridge” between the buyers and senders. Hence, such bridging states can increase their own bargaining power in their interactions with other states in the network. Ukraine, which provides transit for the natural gas pipeline from Russia to the European Union, is an example of such a relationship. In the gas dispute of 2009 between Russia and Ukraine, Russia blamed Ukraine for cutting its gas exports to the EU to compensate for Russia cutting gas aimed for Ukraine (though Ukraine denied these allegations) ( Kramer 2009 ). As a result, the EU is now actively involved in all gas-related disputes between the two states to ensure its own energy security, while Russia found itself dependent on the Ukrainian transit powers. This event illustrates that Ukraine's role as a bridging node in relation to the pipeline may give it additional power, power which cannot be accounted for by traditional bilateral models of economic interactions. Thus, while bridging roles may be absent or difficult to identify in some economic areas, they can be highly important in understanding the differences of sanction consequences for bridging countries.

The Network-Based Interdependence Approach: New Research Areas and Its Limitations

The theoretical approach we proposed could help to illuminate the following currently understudied issues. Considering their recent rise and developments, cryptocurrency markets (based on blockchain networks) can be one of the most important areas for understanding new challenges for sanctions. While Farell and Newman (2019 , 78) mention that a “blockchain-based payment system” can reduce state dependence on the SWIFT system, research on cryptocurrency markets is important in understanding other recent challenges facing sanctions. The presence of alternative financial networks can diminish the impacts (and effectiveness) of financial sanctions imposed not only on states, but on such nonstate actors as terrorists, criminal groups, and others. Such effects of cryptocurrency markets require studies of the new potential of state and nonstate actors to adjust and boost sanctions, or newer methods of control over financial flows via novel attempts of national legislation, to control markets.

Sanction scholars may also refer to the understanding of networked interdependence to study the relationships between sanctions and migration flows within the context of global security networks. Some sanctions cause an increase in emigration from targeted states, thus creating potential consequences for third-country states and sanction senders. However, understanding such consequences is likely to require the consideration of the structure and constraints of the economic and logistic networks used by the affected people.

Future research may also focus on the effects of sanctions on some indirectly related networks. For example, academic networks of knowledge exchange present the potential to experience the impacts of sanctions in terms of diminishing academic exchange and overseas funding (due to financial restrictions imposed on IO in relation to scholars of some countries [e.g., EU funding for Russia-based scholars] or decreasing national funds in targeted countries). Thus, considering the network-based nature of many interactions targeted by sanctions, influencing sanction consequences or being indirectly influenced by sanction imposition, presents an opportunity to investigate otherwise understudied areas of sanction consequences, as well as sanction research in general.

While demonstrating the benefits of the networked interdependence approach for sanction consequence research, we acknowledge that it has limitations. This approach can be difficult to implement within large- N studies when networks influenced by sanctions involve a very high number of different actors, especially if we include nonstate actors. Likewise, some interactions between actors may be difficult to capture due to a lack of related data. While in time more detailed data on interstate interactions may be available, current studies may be limited by such issues. Moreover, even if some political and humanitarian costs depend on economic impacts or may be directly related to the networked nature of these interactions, we acknowledge that currently such an approach is mostly limited to the economic effects of sanctions. Finally, it may help identify only some of the factors influencing sanction consequences. Thus, one needs to complement this approach with political, economic, or other theories related to the specific issues affected by sanctions and the domestic restrictions that states face. However, such limitations do not diminish the importance of considering the network-based nature of social relations as a framework in which all other mechanisms take place. Therefore, we believe that further studies using such an approach could advance sanction research.

In this article, we critically evaluate the current rich and fragmented scholarship on sanction consequences. We then identify the main limitations and challenges of the existing literature. We argue that the theoretical and methodological fragmentation of the literature, the weaknesses of datasets on sanctions, a US-centric focus of most sanction-related literature, and a limited understanding of the influence of secondary sanctions on sanction consequences are among the main problems of the existing literature. We propose networked interdependence approach to remedy some of these limitations as well as the current fragmentation of the scholarship.

We present a shared approach to studying sanction consequences by accounting for different degrees of interconnectedness and interdependence between the sender/target and other states. Applying the logic of asymmetrical network-based interdependence, we argue that what combines all sanction consequences research is that all sanctions are conducted within the context of interdependent states located within hierarchical networks and thus possess different capacities at restricting economic transactions or adjusting to them. We show how an interdependence-based understanding of sanction consequences can help one understand sanction consequences in the context of an increased use of cryptocurrency or the recent migration trends. Considering networked interdependence could help evaluate the adaptability of targets with a larger number of connections within the related network or the targets’ capacity to create/strengthen their own hubs of economic networks with other states. Locating sanctions within such a framework of interdependence will allow one to consider secondary sanctions, sanction boosters, adaptations as adjustments of other states connected to the network, and systemic consequences related to global changes within the networks of flows of goods, finances, and investments.

The authors' names are listed in alphabetical order and denote equal contribution. The authors would like to thank Dursun Pekşen and the Journal's anonymous reviewers and editors for their helpful comments on earlier versions of this article.

Alternative goals of sanctions include “(a) deterrence, (b) compliance, (c) punishment, (d) destabilization, (e) limitation of conflict, (f) solidarity, (g) symbolism, (h) signaling” ( Doxey 1996b , 54–55) and, depending on one's judgment, may fall within or outside of Giumelli's (2011) categorization.

Threats might also motivate protests by signaling avoidable economic hardships.

Recent reports argue that the United States’ sanctions on Iran could “fuel a new refugee crisis—in Turkey” ( Cunningham 2020 ).

Afesorgbor Sylvanus Kwaku , Mahadevan Renuka . 2016 . “ The Impact of Economic Sanctions on Income Inequality of Target States .” World Development 83 : 1 – 11 .

Google Scholar

Allen Susan Hannah . 2008 . “ The Domestic Political Costs of Economic Sanctions .” The Journal of Conflict Resolution 52 ( 6 ): 916 – 44 .

Allen Susan Hannah , Cilizoglu Menevis , Lektzian David , Su Yi-Hao . 2020 . “ Essay 3: The Consequences of Economic Sanctions .” International Studies Perspectives 21 ( 4 ): 438 – 77 .

Allen Susan Hannah , Lektzian David . 2013 . “ Economic Sanctions: A Blunt Instrument? ” Journal of Peace Research 50 ( 1 ): 121 – 35 .

Amuzegar J. 1997 . “ Adjusting to Sanctions .” Foreign Affairs 76 ( 3 ): 31 – 41 .

Andreas Peter . 2010 . “ Unintended Criminalizing Consequences of Sanctions: Lessons from the Balkans .” In Rethinking Security Governance: The Problem of Unintended Consequences , edited by Daase C. , C. , Friesendorf , 102 – 26 . London : Routledge .

Google Preview

Ankudinov Andrei , Ibragimov Rustam , Lebedev Oleg . 2017 . “ Sanctions and the Russian Stock Market .” Research in International Business and Finance 40 : 150 – 62 .

Arnold Aaron . 2016 . “ The True Costs of Financial Sanctions .” Survival 58 ( 3 ): 77 – 100 .

Balanov Aleksei . 2017 . “ When Words Are Worse Than Bullets: A Study of Corruption as an Unintended Consequence of Threats of Sanctions .” Dayton, OH : Wright State University .

Barry Colin M. , Kleinberg Katja B. . 2015 . “ Profiting from Sanctions: Economic Coercion and US Foreign Direct Investment in Third-Party States .” International Organization 69 ( 4 ): 881 – 912 .

Basu Arnab K. , Chau Nancy H. , Grote Ulrike . 2006 . “ Guaranteed Manufactured without Child Labor: The Economics of Consumer Boycotts, Social Labeling and Trade Sanctions .” Review of Development Economics 10 ( 3 ): 466 – 91 .

Bayard T.O. , Pelzman J. , Perezlopez J. . 1983 . “ Stakes and Risks in Economic Sanctions .” World Economy 6 ( 1 ): 73 – 87 .

Besedeš Tibor , Goldbach Stefan , Nitsch Volker . 2017 . “ You're Banned! The Effect of Sanctions on German Cross-Border Financial Flows .” Economic Policy 32 ( 90 ): 263 – 318 .

Bessler Manuel , Garfield Richard , Hugh Gerard Mc . 2004 . “ Sanction Assessment Handbook: Assessing the Humanitarian Implications of Sanctions .” United Nations Office for the Coordination of Humanitarian Affairs and Inter-Agency Standing Committee .

Biersteker T.J. 2010 . “ Targeted Sanctions and Individual Human Rights .” International Journal 65 ( 1 ): 99 – 117 .

Biersteker Thomas J. , Eckert Sue E. , Tourinho Marcos , Zuzana Hudáková . 2018 . “ UN Targeted Sanctions Datasets (1991–2013) .” Journal of Peace Research 55 ( 3 ): 404 – 12 .

Biglaiser G. , Lektzian David . 2011 . “ The Effect of Sanctions on US Foreign Direct Investment .” International Organization 65 ( 3 ): 531 – 51 .

Black P.A. , Cooper H. . 1987 . “ On the Welfare and Employment Effects of Economic Sanctions .” South African Journal of Economics 55 ( 1 ): 1 – 15 .

Borzyskowski Inken von , Portela Clara . 2016 . Piling on: The Rise of Sanctions Cooperation between Regional Organizations, the United States, and the EU , vol. 70 . Berlin : DEU. Arbeitspapier .

Botterill Linda Courtenay , McNaughton Anne . 2008 . “ Laying the Foundations for the Wheat Scandal: UN Sanctions, Private Actors and the Cole Inquiry .” Australian Journal of Political Science 43 ( 4 ): 583 – 98 .

Brooks Risa A. 2002 . “ Sanctions and Regime Type: What Works, and When? ” Security Studies 11 ( 4 ): 1 – 50 .

Buck Lori , Gallant Nicole , Nossal Kim Richard . 1998 . “ Sanctions as a Gendered Instrument of Statecraft: The Case of Iraq .” Review of International Studies 24 ( 1 ): 69 – 84 .

Canes M.E. 2000 . “ Country Impacts of Multilateral Oil Sanctions .” Contemporary Economic Policy 18 ( 2 ): 135 – 44 .

Carneiro C.D.L . 2014 . “ Economic Sanctions and Human Rights: An Analysis of Competing Enforcement Strategies in Latin America .” Revista Brasileira De Politica Internacional 57 ( 1 ): 197 – 215 .

Carneiro C.D.L. , Apolinário Laerte . 2016 . “ Targeted Versus Conventional Economic Sanctions: What Is at Stake for Human Rights? ” International Interactions 42 ( 4 ): 565 – 89 .

Castagneto-Gissey G. , Nivorozhkin E. . 2016 . “ No Contagion from Russia toward Global Equity Markets after the 2014 International Sanctions .” Economic Analysis and Policy 52 : 79 – 98 .

Choi S.W. , Luo S.L. . 2013 . “ Economic Sanctions, Poverty, and International Terrorism: An Empirical Analysis .” International Interactions 39 ( 2 ): 217 – 45 .

Connolly Richard . 2018 . “ Western Sanctions and the Russian Response .” In Russia's Response to Sanctions: How Western Economic Statecraft Is Reshaping Political Economy in Russia , edited by Connolly Richard , 56 – 77 . Cambridge : Cambridge University Press .

Cooper J.H. 1989 . “ On Income-Distribution and Economic Sanctions .” South African Journal of Economics 57 ( 1 ): 14 – 21 .

Cranmer Skyler J. , Heinrich Tobias , Desmarais Bruce A. . 2014 . “ Reciprocity and the Structural Determinants of the International Sanctions Network .” Social Networks 36 ( Supplement C ): 5 – 22 .

Cunningham Erin . 2020 . “ Trump's Sanctions on Iran Are Helping Fuel a New Refugee Crisis—in Turkey .” Washington Post , January 24, 2020 .

Dorff Cassy , Minhas Shahryar . 2017 . “ When Do States Say Uncle? Network Dependence and Sanction Compliance .” International Interactions 43 ( 4 ): 563 – 88 .

Doxey M. 1980 . “ Economic Sanctions: Benefits and Costs .” World Today 36 ( 12 ): 484 – 89 .

Doxey Margaret P. 1996a . International Sanctions in Contemporary Perspective , 2nd ed. New York : St. Martin's Press .

Doxey Margaret P. . 1996b . International Sanctions in Contemporary Perspective , 2nd ed. New York : St. Martin's Press .

Dreger Christian , Kholodilin Konstantin A. , Ulbricht Dirk , Fidrmuc Jarko . 2016 . “ Between the Hammer and the Anvil: The Impact of Economic Sanctions and Oil Prices on Russia's Ruble .” Journal of Comparative Economics 44 ( 2 ): 295 – 308 .

Drezner D.W. 2000 . “ Bargaining, Enforcement, and Multilateral Sanctions: When Is Cooperation Counterproductive? ” International Organization 54 ( 1 ): 73 – 102 .

Drezner D.W. . 2015 . “ Targeted Sanctions in a World of Global Finance .” International Interactions 41 ( 4 ): 755 – 64 .

Drury A.C. , Li Yitan . 2006 . “ U.S. Economic Sanction Threats against China: Failing to Leverage Better Human Rights .” Foreign Policy Analysis 2 ( 4 ): 307 – 24 .

Drury A.C. , Peksen Dursun . 2012 . “ Women and Economic Statecraft: The Negative Impact International Economic Sanctions Visit on Women .” European Journal of International Relations 20 ( 2 ): 463 – 90 .

Early Bryan R. 2009 . “ Sleeping with Your Friends’ Enemies: An Explanation of Sanctions-Busting Trade .” International Studies Quarterly 53 ( 1 ): 49 – 71 .

Early Bryan R. . 2012 . “ Alliances and Trade with Sanctioned States: A Study of U.S. Economic Sanctions, 1950–2000 .” Journal of Conflict Resolution 56 ( 3 ): 547 – 72 .

Elliott K.A. 2009 . “ Assessing UN Sanctions after the Cold War New and Evolving Standards of Measurement .” International Journal 65 ( 1 ): 85 – 97 .

Elliott Kimberly Ann . 2016 . “ The Impacts of United Nations Targeted Sanction s.” In Targeted Sanctions: The Impacts and Effectiveness of United Nations Action , edited by Tourinho Marcos , Eckert Sue E. , Biersteker Thomas J. , 172 – 89 . Cambridge : Cambridge University Press .

Eriksson Mikael . 2016 . “ The Unintended Consequences of United Nations Targeted Sanction s.” In Targeted Sanctions: The Impacts and Effectiveness of United Nations Action , edited by Tourinho Marcos , Eckert Sue E. , Biersteker Thomas J. , 190 – 219 . Cambridge : Cambridge University Press .

Eriksson Mikael , Wallensteen Peter . 2015 . “ Targeting Sanctions and Ending Armed Conflicts: First Steps Towards a New Research Agenda .” International Affairs 91 ( 6 ): 1387 – 98 .

Escribà-Folch Abel . 2010 . “ Economic Sanctions and the Duration of Civil Conflicts .” Journal of Peace Research 47 ( 2 ): 129 – 41 .

Escribà-Folch Abel . 2012 . “ Authoritarian Responses to Foreign Pressure: Spending, Repression, and Sanctions .” Comparative Political Studies 45 ( 6 ): 683 – 713 .

Escribà-Folch Abel , Wright Joseph . 2010 . “ Dealing with Tyranny: International Sanctions and the Survival of Authoritarian Rulers .” International Studies Quarterly 54 ( 2 ): 335 – 59 .

Esfahani Mohammad Nasre , Rasoulinezhad Ehsan . 2017 . “ Iran's Trade Policy of Asianization and de-Europeanization under Sanctions .” Journal of Economic Studies 44 ( 4 ): 552 – 67 .

Evenett S.J. 2002 . “ The Impact of Economic Sanctions on South African Exports .” Scottish Journal of Political Economy 49 ( 5 ): 557 – 73 .

Farmer R.D. 2000 . “ Costs of Economic Sanctions to the Sender .” World Economy 23 ( 1 ): 93 – 117 .

Farrell Henry , Newman Abraham L. . 2019 . “ Weaponized Interdependence: How Global Economic Networks Shape State Coercion .” International Security 44 ( 1 ): 42 – 79 .

Fathollah-Nejad A. 2014 . “ Why Sanctions against Iran Are Counterproductive: Conflict Resolution and State–Society Relations .” International Journal 69 ( 1 ): 48 – 65 .

Felbermayr Gabriel , Kirilakha Aleksandra , Syropoulos Constantinos , Yalcin Erdal , Yotov Yoto V. . 2020 . “ The Global Sanctions Data Base .” European Economic Review 129 : 103561 .

Freeman N.J. 1993 . “ United-States Economic Sanctions against Vietnam: International-Business and Development Repercussions .” Columbia Journal of World Business 28 ( 2 ): 12 – 22 .

Galtung Johan . 1967 . “ On the Effects of International Economic Sanctions: With Examples from the Case of Rhodesia .” World Politics 19 ( 3 ): 378 – 416 .

Garoupa N.R. , Gata J.E. . 2002 . “ A Theory of International Conflict Management and Sanctioning .” Public Choice 110 ( 1–2 ): 41 – 65 .

Gharehgozli Orkideh . 2017 . “ An Estimation of the Economic Cost of Recent Sanctions on Iran Using the Synthetic Control Method .” Economics Letters 157 : 141 – 44 .

Giumelli Francesco . 2011 . Coercing, Constraining and Signalling: Explaining UN and EU Sanctions after the Cold War . Colchester : ECPR Press .

Giumelli Francesco . 2017 . “ The Redistributive Impact of Restrictive Measures on EU Members: Winners and Losers from Imposing Sanctions on Russia .” JCMS: Journal of Common Market Studies 55 ( 5 ): 1062 – 80 .

Gordon J. 2011 . “ Smart Sanctions Revisited .” Ethics & International Affairs 25 ( 3 ): 315 – 35 .

Grauvogel Julia , Licht Amanda A. , Christian von Soest . 2017 . “ Sanctions and Signals: How International Sanction Threats Trigger Domestic Protest in Targeted Regimes .” International Studies Quarterly 61 ( 1 ): 86 – 97 .

Grauvogel Julia , von Soest Christian . 2014 . “ Claims to Legitimacy Count: Why Sanctions Fail to Instigate Democratisation in Authoritarian Regimes .” European Journal of Political Research 53 ( 4 ): 635 – 53 .

Gurvich Evsey , Prilepskiy Ilya . 2015 . “ The Impact of Financial Sanctions on the Russian Economy .” Russian Journal of Economics 1 ( 4 ): 359 – 85 .

Gutmann Jerg , Neuenkirch Matthias , Neumeier Florian . 2020 . “ Sanctioned to Death? The Impact of Economic Sanctions on Life Expectancy and Its Gender Gap .” The Journal of Development Studies 57 ( 1 ): 139 – 62 .

Haidar Jamal Ibrahim . 2017 . “ Sanctions and Export Deflection: Evidence from Iran .” Economic Policy 32 ( 90 ): 319 – 55 .

Hatipoglu Emre , Peksen Dursun . 2018 . “ Economic Sanctions and Banking Crises in Target Economies .” Defence and Peace Economics 29 ( 2 ): 171 – 89 .

Heinrich Tobias , Kobayashi Yoshiharu , Peterson Timothy M. . 2017 . “ Sanction Consequences and Citizen Support: A Survey Experiment .” International Studies Quarterly 61 ( 1 ): 98 – 106 .

Hellquist Elin . 2016 . “ Either with Us or against Us? Third-Country Alignment with EU Sanctions against Russia/Ukraine .” Cambridge Review of International Affairs 29 ( 3 ): 997 – 1021 .

Hellquist Elin , Palestini Stefano . 2020 . “ Regional Sanctions and the Struggle for Democracy: Introduction to the Special Issue .” International Political Science Review 0192512120968109 . doi: 10.1177/0192512120968109 .

Herring E. 2002 . “ Between Iraq and a Hard Place: A Critique of the British Government's Case for UN Economic Sanctions .” Review of International Studies 28 ( 1 ): 39 – 56 .

Hufbauer G.C. , Elliott K.A. , Cyrus T. , Winston E. . 1997 . “ US Economic Sanctions: Their Impact on Trade, Jobs, and Wages .” Working Paper Series, Peterson Institute for International Economics .

Hufbauer G.C. , Schott J.J. , Elliott K.A. , Oegg B. . 2009 . Economic Sanctions Reconsidered , 3rd ed. Washington, DC : PIIE .

Hultman Lisa , Peksen Dursun . 2017 . “ Successful or Counterproductive Coercion? The Effect of International Sanctions on Conflict Intensity .” Journal of Conflict Resolution 61 ( 6 ): 1315 – 39 .

Jaeger Mark Daniel . 2016 . “ Constructing Sanctions: Rallying around the Target in Zimbabwe .” Cambridge Review of International Affairs 29 ( 3 ): 952 – 69 .

Jafarey S. , Lahiri S. . 2002 . “ Will Trade Sanctions Reduce Child Labour? The Role of Credit Markets .” Journal of Development Economics 68 ( 1 ): 137 – 56 .

Jones E. , Whitworth A. . 2014 . “ The Unintended Consequences of European Sanctions on Russia .” Survival 56 ( 5 ): 21 – 30 .

Jones Lee . 2015 . Societies under Siege: Exploring How International Economic Sanctions (Do Not) Work . New York : Oxford University Press .

Kaempfer William H. , Lowenberg Anton D. . 1988 . “ The Theory of International Economic Sanctions: A Public Choice Approach .” The American Economic Review 78 ( 4 ): 786 – 93 .

Karimi M. , Haghpanah S. . 2015 . “ The Effects of Economic Sanctions on Disease Specific Clinical Outcomes of Patients with Thalassemia and Hemophilia in Iran .” Health Policy 119 ( 2 ): 239 – 43 .

Keohane Robert O. , Nye Joseph S. . 1987 . “ Power and Interdependence Revisited .” Review of Power and Interdependence, Robert O. Keohane, Joseph S. Nye, Jr. International Organization 41 ( 4 ): 725 – 53 .

Khan H.A. 1988 . “ Impact of Trade Sanctions on South-Africa: A Social Accounting Matrix Approach .” Contemporary Policy Issues 6 ( 4 ): 130 – 40 .

Kim Yeon Joo . 2014 . “ Economic Sanctions and the Rhetorical Responses of Totalitarian Regimes: Examining North Korean Rhetorical Strategies, 1949–2010 .” Communist and Post-Communist Studies 47 ( 2 ): 159 – 69 .

Kirshner J. 1997 . “ The Microfoundations of Economic Sanctions .” Security Studies 6 ( 3 ): 32 – 64 .

Kramer Andrew E. 2009 . “ Russia Cuts Gas, and Europe Shivers .” The New York Times , January 6. 2009 .

Lacy Dean , Niou Emerson M.S. . 2004 . “ A Theory of Economic Sanctions and Issue Linkage: The Roles of Preferences, Information, and Threats .” Journal of Politics 66 ( 1 ): 25 – 42 .

Lee Jong-Woon , Gray Kevin . 2017 . “ Cause for Optimism? Financial Sanctions and the Rise of the Sino-North Korean Border Economy .” Review of International Political Economy 24 ( 3 ): 424 – 53 .

Lektzian David , Biglaiser G. . 2013 . “ Investment, Opportunity, and Risk: Do US Sanctions Deter or Encourage Global Investment? ” International Studies Quarterly 57 ( 1 ): 65 – 78 .

Lektzian David , Sprecher Christopher M. . 2007 . “ Sanctions, Signals, and Militarized Conflict .” American Journal of Political Science 51 ( 2 ): 415 – 31 .

Lohmann Sascha . 2016 . “ The Convergence of Transatlantic Sanction Policy against Iran .” Cambridge Review of International Affairs 29 ( 3 ): 930 – 51 .

Lv Zhike , Xu Ting . 2017 . “ The Effect of Economic Sanctions on Ethnic Violence of Target States: A Panel Data Analysis .” The Social Science Journal 54 ( 1 ): 102 – 5 .

Mack A. , Khan A. . 2000 . “ The Efficacy of UN Sanctions .” Security Dialogue 31 ( 3 ): 279 – 92 .

Marinov Nikolay . 2005 . “ Do Economic Sanctions Destabilize Country Leaders? ” American Journal of Political Science 49 ( 3 ): 564 – 76 .

McDonald III , Bruce D. , Vincent Reitano . 2016 . “ Sanction Failure: Economic Growth, Defense Expenditures, and the Islamic Republic of Iran .” Armed Forces & Society 42 ( 4 ): 635 – 54 .

McLean Elena V. , Hinkkainen Kaisa H. , Calle Luis De la , Bapat Navin A. . 2016 . “ Economic Sanctions and the Dynamics of Terrorist Campaigns .” Conflict Management and Peace Science 35 ( 4 ): 378 – 401 .

McLean Elena V. , Roblyer Dwight A. . 2017 . “ Public Support for Economic Sanctions: An Experimental Analysis .” Foreign Policy Analysis 13 ( 1 ): 233 – 54 .

McLean Elena V. , Whang Taehee . 2019 . “ Economic Sanctions and Government Spending Adjustments: The Case of Disaster Preparedness .” British Journal of Political Science 51 ( 1 ): 394 – 411 .

Meyer Jeffrey A. 2009 . “ Second Thoughts on Secondary Sanctions .” University of Pennsylvania Journal of International Law 30 ( 3 ): 905 .

Miller Nicholas L. 2014 . “ The Secret Success of Nonproliferation Sanctions .” International Organization 68 ( 4 ): 913 – 44 .

Miyagiwa Kaz , Ohno Yuka . 2015 . “ Nuclear Bombs and Economic Sanctions .” Southern Economic Journal 82 ( 2 ): 635 – 46 .

Moret Erica S. 2015 . “ Humanitarian Impacts of Economic Sanctions on Iran and Syria .” European Security 24 ( 1 ): 120 – 40 .

Morgan T. Clifton , Bapat Navin , Kobayashi Yoshiharu . 2014 . “ Threat and Imposition of Economic Sanctions 1945–2005: Updating the TIES Dataset .” Conflict Management and Peace Science 31 ( 5 ): 541 – 58 .

Morgan T.C. , Schwebach V.L. . 1995 . “ Economic Sanctions as an Instrument of Foreign Policy: The Role of Domestic Politics .” International Interactions 21 ( 3 ): 247 – 63 .

Naghavi Alireza , Pignataro Giuseppe . 2015 . “ Theocracy and Resilience against Economic Sanctions .” Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 111 : 1 – 12 .

Neuenkirch Matthias , Neumeier Florian . 2015 . “ The Impact of UN and US Economic Sanctions on GDP Growth .” European Journal of Political Economy 40 : 110 – 25 .

Neuenkirch Matthias , Neumeier Florian . 2016 . “ The Impact of US Sanctions on Poverty .” Journal of Development Economics 121 : 110 – 19 .

Newman M.E.J. , Park Juyong . 2003 . “ Why Social Networks Are Different from Other Types of Networks .” Physical Review E 68 ( 3 ): 036122 .

Oechslin Manuel . 2014 . “ Targeting Autocrats: Economic Sanctions and Regime Change .” European Journal of Political Economy 36 : 24 – 40 .

Pak Olga , Kretzschmar Gavin Lee . 2016 . “ Western Sanctions: Only Half the Challenge to Russia's Economic Union .” Research in International Business and Finance 38 : 577 – 92 .

Pape Robert A. 1997 . “ Why Economic Sanctions Do Not Work .” International Security 22 ( 2 ): 90 – 136 .

Park John S. 2014 . “ The Key to the North Korean Targeted Sanctions Puzzle .” The Washington Quarterly 37 ( 3 ): 199 – 214 .

Parker Dominic P. , Foltz Jeremy D. , Elsea David . 2016 . “ Unintended Consequences of Sanctions for Human Rights: Conflict Minerals and Infant Mortality .” The Journal of Law and Economics 59 ( 4 ): 731 – 74 .

Paul T.V. 1996 . “ Strengthening the Non-proliferation Regime: The Role of Coercive Sanctions .” International Journal 51 ( 3 ): 440 – 65 .

Peksen Dursun . 2009 . “ Better or Worse? The Effect of Economic Sanctions on Human Rights .” Journal of Peace Research 46 ( 1 ): 59 – 77 .

Peksen Dursun . 2010 . “ Coercive Diplomacy and Press Freedom: An Empirical Assessment of the Impact of Economic Sanctions on Media Openness .” International Political Science Review 31 ( 4 ): 449 – 69 .

Peksen Dursun . 2011 . “ Economic Sanctions and Human Security: The Public Health Effect of Economic Sanctions .” Foreign Policy Analysis 7 ( 3 ): 237 – 51 .

Peksen Dursun . 2016 . “ Economic Sanctions and Official Ethnic Discrimination in Targeted Countries, 1950–2003 .” Defense and Peace Economics 27 ( 4 ): 480 – 502 .

Peksen Dursun . 2017 . “ How Do Target Leaders Survive Economic Sanctions? The Adverse Effect of Sanctions on Private Property and Wealth .” Foreign Policy Analysis 13 ( 1 ): 215 – 32 .

Peksen Dursun . 2019 . “ When Do Imposed Economic Sanctions Work? A Critical Review of the Sanctions Effectiveness Literature .” Defence and Peace Economics 30 ( 6 ): 635 – 47 .

Peksen Dursun , Drury A.C. . 2010 . “ Coercive or Corrosive: The Negative Impact of Economic Sanctions on Democracy .” International Interactions 36 ( 3 ): 240 – 64 .

Peksen Dursun , Son Byunghwan . 2015 . “ Economic Coercion and Currency Crises in Target Countries .” Journal of Peace Research 52 ( 4 ): 448 – 62 .

Peterson T.M. 2013 . “ Sending a Message: The Reputation Effect of US Sanction Threat Behavior .” International Studies Quarterly 57 ( 4 ): 672 – 82 .

Peterson T.M. . 2014 . “ Taking the Cue: The Response to US Human Rights Sanctions against Third Parties .” Conflict Management and Peace Science 31 ( 2 ): 145 – 67 .

Peterson T.M. , Drury A.C. . 2011 . “ Sanctioning Violence: The Effect of Third-Party Economic Coercion on Militarized Conflict .” Journal of Conflict Resolution 55 ( 4 ): 580 – 605 .

Peterson Timothy M. 2018 . “ Reconsidering Economic Leverage and Vulnerability: Trade Ties, Sanction Threats, and the Success of Economic Coercion .” Conflict Management and Peace Science 37 ( 4 ): 409 – 29 .

Pond Amy . 2015 . “ Economic Sanctions and Demand for Protection .” Journal of Conflict Resolution 61 ( 5 ): 1073 – 94 . doi: 10.1177/0022002715596777.

Rosenberg E. , Drezner D.W. , Solomon-Strauss J. , Goldman Z.K. . 2016 . The New Tools of Economic Warfare: Effects and Effectiveness of Contemporary U.S. Financial Sanctions . Washington, DC : Center for a New American Security .

Seeberg Peter . 2016 . “ The Crisis in Syria, International and Regional Sanctions, and the Transformation of the Political Order in the Levant .” In The Levant in Turmoil: Syria, Palestine, and the Transformation of Middle Eastern Politics , edited by Beck Martin , Jung Dietrich , Seeberg Peter , 101 – 22 . New York : Palgrave Macmillan US .

Setayesh Sogol , Mackey Tim K. . 2016 . “ Addressing the Impact of Economic Sanctions on Iranian Drug Shortages in the Joint Comprehensive Plan of Action: Promoting Access to Medicines and Health Diplomacy .” Globalization and Health 12 ( 1 ): 12 – 31 .

Shahabi S. , Fazlalizadeh H. , Stedman J. , Chuang L. , Shariftabrizi A. , Ram R. . 2015 . “ The Impact of International Economic Sanctions on Iranian Cancer Healthcare .” Health Policy 119 ( 10 ): 1309 – 18 .

Shin Geiguen , Choi Seung-Whan , Luo Shali . 2015 . “ Do Economic Sanctions Impair Target Economies? ” International Political Science Review 37 ( 4 ): 485 – 99 .

Silva Paul M. , Selden Zachary . 2019 . “ Economic Interdependence and Economic Sanctions: A Case Study of European Union Sanctions on Russia .” Cambridge Review of International Affairs 33 ( 2 ): 229 – 51 .

Slavov Slavi T. 2007 . “ Innocent or Not-So-innocent Bystanders: Evidence from the Gravity Model of International Trade about the Effects of UN Sanctions on Neighbour Countries .” World Economy 30 ( 11 ): 1701 – 25 .

Targeted Sanctions Consortium . 2014 . Targeted Sanctions Consortium Database Codebook .

Tourinho Marcos . 2015 . “ Towards a World Police? The Implications of Individual UN Targeted Sanctions .” International Affairs 91 ( 6 ): 1399 – 1412 .

van Bergeijk Peter A.G. 1995 . “ The Impact of Economic Sanctions in the 1990s .” The World Economy 18 ( 3 ): 443 – 55 .

van Bergeijk Peter A.G. . 2019 . “ Can the Sanction Debate Be Resolved? ” CESifo Forum 20 ( 4 ): 3 – 8 .

Van Bergeijk Peter A.G. , Siddiquee Muhammad S.H. . 2017 . “ Biased Sanctions? Methodological Change in Economic Sanctions Reconsidered and Its Implications .” International Interactions 43 ( 5 ): 879 – 93 .

Veebel Viljar , Markus Raul . 2018 . “ The Bust, the Boom and the Sanctions in Trade Relations with Russia .” Journal of International Studies 11 ( 1 ): 9 – 20 .

von Soest Christian , Wahman Michael . 2015 . “ Are Democratic Sanctions Really Counterproductive? ” Democratization 22 ( 6 ): 957 – 80 .

Wagner R. Harrison . 1988 . “ Economic Interdependence, Bargaining Power, and Political Influence .” International Organization 42 ( 3 ): 461 – 83 .

Walldorf C. William . 2014 . “ Sanctions, Regime Type, and Democratization: Lessons from U.S.–Central American Relations in the 1980s .” Political Science Quarterly 129 ( 4 ): 643 – 74 .

Watanabe S. 1987 . “ Technological Capability and Industrialization: Effects of Aid and Sanctions in the United Republic of Tanzania and Zimbabve .” International Labour Review 126 ( 5 ): 525 – 41 .

Webb Clayton . 2018 . “ Power Politics or Public Pandering? An Empirical Investigation of Economic Sanctions and Presidential Approval .” International Interactions 44 ( 3 ): 491 – 509 .

Weiss T.G. 1999 . “ Sanctions as a Foreign Policy Tool: Weighing Humanitarian Impulses .” Journal of Peace Research 36 ( 5 ): 499 – 509 .

Whang Taehee . 2011 . “ Playing to the Home Crowd? Symbolic Use of Economic Sanctions in the United States .” International Studies Quarterly 55 ( 3 ): 787 – 801 .

Wood Reed M. 2008. “ ‘A Hand upon the Throat of the Nation’: Economic Sanctions and State Repression, 1976–2001 .” International Studies Quarterly 52 ( 3 ): 489 – 513 .

Yang Jiawen , Askari Hossein , Forrer John , Teegen Hildy . 2004 . “ US Economic Sanctions against China: Who Gets Hurt? ” World Economy 27 ( 7 ): 1047 – 81 .

Yang Jiawen , Askari Hossein , Forrer John , Zhu Lili . 2009 . “ How Do US Economic Sanctions Affect EU's Trade with Target Countries? ” World Economy 32 ( 8 ): 1223 – 44 .

Month: Total Views:
June 2021 246
July 2021 317
August 2021 293
September 2021 391
October 2021 588
November 2021 586
December 2021 599
January 2022 954
February 2022 1,745
March 2022 4,449
April 2022 2,066
May 2022 1,620
June 2022 932
July 2022 798
August 2022 675
September 2022 792
October 2022 1,141
November 2022 1,180
December 2022 845
January 2023 762
February 2023 796
March 2023 1,066
April 2023 1,293
May 2023 1,248
June 2023 728
July 2023 722
August 2023 714
September 2023 809
October 2023 978
November 2023 1,124
December 2023 916
January 2024 846
February 2024 1,038
March 2024 1,251
April 2024 1,037
May 2024 1,247
June 2024 835

Email alerts

Citing articles via.

  • Recommend to your Library

Affiliations

  • Online ISSN 1468-2486
  • Print ISSN 1521-9488
  • Copyright © 2024 International Studies Association
  • About Oxford Academic
  • Publish journals with us
  • University press partners
  • What we publish
  • New features  
  • Open access
  • Institutional account management
  • Rights and permissions
  • Get help with access
  • Accessibility
  • Advertising
  • Media enquiries
  • Oxford University Press
  • Oxford Languages
  • University of Oxford

Oxford University Press is a department of the University of Oxford. It furthers the University's objective of excellence in research, scholarship, and education by publishing worldwide

  • Copyright © 2024 Oxford University Press
  • Cookie settings
  • Cookie policy
  • Privacy policy
  • Legal notice

This Feature Is Available To Subscribers Only

Sign In or Create an Account

This PDF is available to Subscribers Only

For full access to this pdf, sign in to an existing account, or purchase an annual subscription.

University of Minnesota Twin Cities

University digital conservancy, essays on economic sanctions.

Thumbnail Image

View/Download File

Persistent link to this item, journal title, journal issn, volume title, published date, description, collections, series/report number, funding information, isbn identifier, doi identifier, previously published citation, suggested citation.

Content distributed via the University Digital Conservancy may be subject to additional license and use restrictions applied by the depositor. By using these files, users agree to the Terms of Use . Materials in the UDC may contain content that is disturbing and/or harmful. For more information, please see our statement on harmful content in digital repositories .

Potential EU Economic Sanctions in Hungary: An Evaluation

Add to collection, downloadable content.

economic sanctions thesis

  • July 24, 2019
  • Affiliation: College of Arts and Sciences, Department of Political Science
  • Hungary’s economic relationship with the European Union is one that may be characterized by asymmetrical interdependence. Recent events in Hungary suggest an advance of illiberal governance practices in Hungary, which would contradict with stated EU interests in promoting liberal democracy and rule of law. This paper seeks to provide some explanation regarding why economic sanctions from the EU may not be enough threat to deter Hungary from exhibiting behavior that directly violates fundamental EU values and principles, even given its economic dependence on the EU. This will be done through an evaluation of EU capacity to impose sanctions on its member states, the competency of economic sanctions in addressing illiberal regimes, and Orbán’s potential reasons for an illiberal turn. In the final section, the paper analyses EU approaches to economic sanctions policy and comments on the steps taken so far regarding potential economic sanctions on Hungary.
  • European studies
  • Democratic Backsliding
  • Rule of Law
  • European Union
  • Conditionality
  • Economic Sanctions
  • https://doi.org/10.17615/hhqz-7c62
  • Masters Thesis
  • Marks, Gary
  • Maxwell, Rahsaan
  • Hooghe, Liesbet
  • Master of Arts
  • University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill Graduate School

This work has no parents.

Thumbnail Title Date Uploaded Visibility Actions
2019-07-24 Public

Select type of work

Master's papers.

Deposit your masters paper, project or other capstone work. Theses will be sent to the CDR automatically via ProQuest and do not need to be deposited.

Scholarly Articles and Book Chapters

Deposit a peer-reviewed article or book chapter. If you would like to deposit a poster, presentation, conference paper or white paper, use the “Scholarly Works” deposit form.

Undergraduate Honors Theses

Deposit your senior honors thesis.

Scholarly Journal, Newsletter or Book

Deposit a complete issue of a scholarly journal, newsletter or book. If you would like to deposit an article or book chapter, use the “Scholarly Articles and Book Chapters” deposit option.

Deposit your dataset. Datasets may be associated with an article or deposited separately.

Deposit your 3D objects, audio, images or video.

Poster, Presentation, Protocol or Paper

Deposit scholarly works such as posters, presentations, research protocols, conference papers or white papers. If you would like to deposit a peer-reviewed article or book chapter, use the “Scholarly Articles and Book Chapters” deposit option.

UTC Scholar

  • UTC Scholar Home
  • UTC Library

Preserving and Sharing UTC's Knowledge

  • < Previous

Home > Student Research, Creative Works, and Publications > Honors Theses > 77

Honors Theses

An ethics of economic sanctions.

Macallee N. Goldman , University of Tennessee at Chattanooga Follow

Dept. of Philosophy and Religion

University of Tennessee at Chattanooga

Place of Publication

Chattanooga (Tenn.)

This paper provides an ethical analysis of smart sanctions under the combined framework of the categorical imperative and utilitarianism. Developing an ethical model that also encompasses sanction effectiveness as a means of evaluation, this paper argues that smart sanctions should not be used by countries and legislative bodies as tools of expression or of achieving goals without efficiency considerations grounded in this ethical framework. Only when they clearly meet the criteria of utilitarianism and the categorical imperative should smart sanctions be used. By doing so sanction effectiveness is argued to be maximized, in both ethical and empirical context.

B. A.; An honors thesis submitted to the faculty of the University of Tennessee at Chattanooga in partial fulfillment of the requirements of the degree of Bachelor of Arts.

Economic sanctions; Sanctions (International law)

Economic sanctions; Smart sanctions; Utilitarianism; Categorical imperative; Clean-hands; Target sanctions

Document Type

http://rightsstatements.org/vocab/InC/1.0/

http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/3.0/

Recommended Citation

Goldman, Macallee N., "An ethics of economic sanctions" (2016). Honors Theses. https://scholar.utc.edu/honors-theses/77

Since June 23, 2016

Included in

Economics Commons

Advanced Search

  • Notify me via email or RSS
  • Collections
  • Disciplines

Author Corner

  • Submission Guidelines
  • Submit Research

Home | About | FAQ | My Account | Accessibility Statement

Privacy Copyright

share this!

June 20, 2024

This article has been reviewed according to Science X's editorial process and policies . Editors have highlighted the following attributes while ensuring the content's credibility:

fact-checked

trusted source

Economists reveal the costs of sanctions

by Gunnar Bartsch, Julius-Maximilians-Universität Würzburg

economy

What effect do economic sanctions have on the countries affected, such as Russia or Iran? What impact do they have on the sanctioning states? And is there possibly an ideal coalition of sanction partners? Economists from Würzburg, Kiel, Berlin and Bielefeld have analyzed these questions. They have now published their findings in Economic Policy .

Economic sanctions can be a double-edged sword. On the one hand, they usually reduce gross domestic product and thus prosperity in the affected countries, as intended. On the other hand, however, they can also have a severe impact on the economies of the sanctioning countries. However, a skillful selection of the countries involved in the sanctions measures could significantly mitigate these undesirable negative consequences.

These are the key findings of a new study that has now been published in the journal Economic Policy. Economists Sonali Chowdhry (DIW Berlin), Julian Hinz (Bielefeld University & IfW Kiel), Katrin Kamm (IfW Kiel) and Joschka Wanner (University of Würzburg & IfW Kiel) are responsible for the study. The study focuses on the sanctions against Iran in 2012 in response to its nuclear program and against Russia following the violent annexation of Crimea in 2014.

Analyzing prices, prosperity and trade flows

"In our analyses, we focused on the economic effects of sanctions, for example on prices and prosperity in the target country, as well as on trade flows," says Joschka Wanner, Junior Professor of Quantitative International and Environmental Economics at Julius-Maximilians-Universität Würzburg (JMU), describing the approach. As a first step, the team analyzed the extent to which these parameters have changed as a result of the sanctions.

In fact, the calculations for Iran show a real decline in gross domestic product of 1.9% as a result of the sanctions. For Russia, the figure is 1.44%—based on the sanctions from 2014. The sanctions following the attack on Ukraine do not yet play a role in this study. "1.4 or 1.9% may not sound like much. However, from an economic perspective, this is a full-blown recession," says Wanner.

Maximum sanction potential not reached

The group compared these real developments with the maximum potential of the sanctions under various conditions—either by including more countries in the sanctions or by extending them to all goods. "According to our calculations, in the case of Iran, the current coalition achieves around 39% of what would be possible in terms of a decline in gross domestic product—compared to the case in which all countries participate in the sanctions," explains Wanner. For Russia, this figure is just under 58%.

These figures are partly even more drastic if the current scenario is compared with the case in which the sanctions apply to all goods, i.e. there are no more exceptions. In this case, the current coalition only achieves 47% of the possible decline in GDP for Iran. And 16% for Russia.

High costs for some stakeholders

When sanctions are imposed, it is not only the sanctioned countries that suffer—the study also shows this. However, there are major differences. "While larger economies such as the U.S., Japan and Germany get off relatively lightly, smaller countries such as Malta, Estonia and Latvia suffer relatively drastic consequences," explains Wanner. This should come as no surprise: if a small country like Latvia restricts trade with its large neighbor Russia, this will inevitably have a greater impact than in the U.S. or Canada.

As a consequence, this means that small countries pay a high price in this case, while the effects of their participation in the sanctions are only reflected in a small loss of welfare for Russia. The study also shows how things could be better. "Instead of the small countries, other states would have to join the coalition. Then the sanctions would have much greater consequences," explains Wanner.

In the case of sanctions against Russia, the economists have calculated that the participation of China, Vietnam, Belarus, Turkey and South Korea in particular would drastically increase the potential for sanctions. This would rise from 58% under the current coalition to 71%—simply by China joining the sanctions coalition.

Transfer payments for particularly affected countries

Of course, it is unlikely that China will join a coalition of Western states against Russia. So what could the coalition do to ensure that as many countries as possible side with it without suffering disproportionately large economic damage? "Financial transfers" is the research team's answer.

"Our results show that 591 million US dollars would have to be mobilized in connection with the sanctions against Iran and 4.8 billion US dollars in the case of Russia so that the members could compensate for their welfare losses due to the respective sanctions," the study states.

The largest contributor to this "compensation fund" would be the U.S., whose combined transfers for both sanctions packages would amount to around 4.4 billion US dollars. They would be followed by the UK (770 million US dollars) and Canada (553 million US dollars).

Provided by Julius-Maximilians-Universität Würzburg

Explore further

Feedback to editors

economic sanctions thesis

The Milky Way's eROSITA bubbles are large and distant

Jun 29, 2024

economic sanctions thesis

Saturday Citations: Armadillos are everywhere; Neanderthals still surprising anthropologists; kids are egalitarian

economic sanctions thesis

NASA astronauts will stay at the space station longer for more troubleshooting of Boeing capsule

economic sanctions thesis

The beginnings of fashion: Paleolithic eyed needles and the evolution of dress

Jun 28, 2024

economic sanctions thesis

Analysis of NASA InSight data suggests Mars hit by meteoroids more often than thought

economic sanctions thesis

New computational microscopy technique provides more direct route to crisp images

economic sanctions thesis

A harmless asteroid will whiz past Earth Saturday. Here's how to spot it

economic sanctions thesis

Tiny bright objects discovered at dawn of universe baffle scientists

economic sanctions thesis

New method for generating monochromatic light in storage rings

economic sanctions thesis

Soft, stretchy electrode simulates touch sensations using electrical signals

Relevant physicsforums posts, biographies, history, personal accounts.

4 hours ago

Who is your favorite Jazz musician and what is your favorite song?

10 hours ago

Today's Fusion Music: T Square, Cassiopeia, Rei & Kanade Sato

Cover songs versus the original track, which ones are better, the balinese alphabet.

Jun 27, 2024

History of Railroad Safety - Spotlight on current derailments

Jun 26, 2024

More from Art, Music, History, and Linguistics

Related Stories

economic sanctions thesis

Researchers build quantitative model with the aim of imposing cost-efficient trade sanctions

Jun 10, 2024

economic sanctions thesis

Economic sanctions can have a major impact on the neighbors of a target nation, research finds

Feb 28, 2024

economic sanctions thesis

How sanctions on Russia play out for the world

Mar 16, 2022

economic sanctions thesis

Sanctions on Russia's businesses haven't worked, says study

Jun 5, 2023

economic sanctions thesis

Crypto exchange Bittrex to pay $24M for violating sanctions

Oct 11, 2022

economic sanctions thesis

Crypto firm Binance pulls out of Russia

Sep 27, 2023

Recommended for you

economic sanctions thesis

Study finds motivation to compete is stronger with in-group members than with outsiders

economic sanctions thesis

Lie-detection AI could provoke people into making careless accusations, researchers warn

economic sanctions thesis

Sharing false political information on social media may be associated with positive schizotypy, research suggests

economic sanctions thesis

How the Meta algorithm influences election advertising

economic sanctions thesis

Reframing voting as 'duty to others' could be key to increasing engagement, turnout

Jun 21, 2024

economic sanctions thesis

Family conditions may have more of an impact on upward social mobility than gender inequality

Jun 20, 2024

Let us know if there is a problem with our content

Use this form if you have come across a typo, inaccuracy or would like to send an edit request for the content on this page. For general inquiries, please use our contact form . For general feedback, use the public comments section below (please adhere to guidelines ).

Please select the most appropriate category to facilitate processing of your request

Thank you for taking time to provide your feedback to the editors.

Your feedback is important to us. However, we do not guarantee individual replies due to the high volume of messages.

E-mail the story

Your email address is used only to let the recipient know who sent the email. Neither your address nor the recipient's address will be used for any other purpose. The information you enter will appear in your e-mail message and is not retained by Phys.org in any form.

Newsletter sign up

Get weekly and/or daily updates delivered to your inbox. You can unsubscribe at any time and we'll never share your details to third parties.

More information Privacy policy

Donate and enjoy an ad-free experience

We keep our content available to everyone. Consider supporting Science X's mission by getting a premium account.

E-mail newsletter

Debate Fact Check: Biden and Trump on the Economy, Immigration and Foreign Policy

By The New York Times

  • Share full article

economic sanctions thesis

President Biden and former President Donald J. Trump faced off on Thursday in the first presidential debate of the general election. We examined their policy claims, personal attacks and their records in office.

Ana Swanson

Ana Swanson

“Economists say that’s going to cost the average American $2,500 a year or more.”

— President Biden on Mr. Trump’s proposal to increase tariffs on most American imports by 10 percent

This is exaggerated.

Estimates of the impact of an overall 10 percent tariff vary, but one recent analysis by the right-leaning American Action Forum estimated that a 10 percent tariff could impose additional annual costs of up to $2,350 per American household.

Another analysis by the Peterson Institute of International Economics found that if Mr. Trump imposed a 10 percent tariff on all goods and a 60 percent tariff on China, it would cost a typical household in the middle of the income distribution about $1,700 in increased expenses each year.

Linda Qiu

“He wants to raise your taxes by four times.”

— Former President Donald J. Trump

Many elements of the 2017 tax cut that Mr. Trump signed into law will expire in 2025, and Mr. Biden has proposed some tax increases on high-income earners and corporations. But this does not amount to a quadrupling of taxes.

The 2017 tax cut is expected to reduce the average tax rate by 1.4 percent in 2025, according to the Urban-Brookings Tax Policy Center, a left-leaning Washington think tank. Most in the top 5 percent of income would see the greatest change, by 2.4 percent.

Mr. Biden has also consistently said that he does not support raising taxes on people making under $400,000 a year and, in his latest budget, proposed extending tax cuts for those making under that threshold. Mr. Biden’s proposals would increase the average tax rate by about 1.9 percent, according to a Tax Policy Center analysis . The top 0.1 percent would see the biggest increase, of about 13.9 percent, while the low-income filers would see a reduction in taxes. That is no where near the 300 percent increase Mr. Trump warned of.

Advertisement

Julian E. Barnes

Julian E. Barnes

“I got them to put up hundreds of billions of dollars. The secretary general of NATO said Trump did the most incredible job ever.”

This needs context..

Mr. Trump made increasing European military spending a corner stone of his presidency, and it did rise during his administration.

But more countries raised their defense spending during the Biden administration. According to NATO report , in 2020, the final year of the Trump administration, military spending rose 4.6 percent and nine countries met the commitment to spend 2 percent of their gross domestic product on defense.

This year, NATO estimated defense spending went up 17.9 percent and 23 of the 32 allies met their financial commitments. While the Biden administration pressed for more European spending, much of the spending has been a result of Russia’s invasion of Ukraine.

Jim Tankersley

Jim Tankersley

“But Social Security, he’s destroying it because millions of people are pouring into our country and they are putting them onto Social Security.”

Mr. Trump has this backward. Undocumented workers often pay taxes that help fund Social Security. But, as the nonpartisan Congressional Budget Office once noted , “most unauthorized immigrants are prohibited from receiving many of the benefits that the federal government provides through Social Security and such need-based programs as food stamps, Medicaid (other than emergency services) and Temporary Assistance for Needy Families.”

“Nancy Pelosi, if you just watched the news from two days ago on tape to her daughter who’s a documentary filmmaker, or they say what she’s saying, ‘Oh, no, it’s my responsibility. I was responsible for this.’ Because I offered them 10,000 soldiers are National Guard. And she turned them down.”

This is misleading..

Mr. Trump is distorting what Representative Nancy Pelosi, then the House speaker, said. Ms. Pelosi did not admit to turning down National Guard troops. She does not have such authority.

The Republican-controlled House Oversight Committee recently released a short video captured by Alexandra Pelosi, Ms. Pelosi’s daughter and a documentary filmmaker, turned over to congressional investigators of the former speaker at the time during the Capitol attack on Jan. 6, 2021. The full footage has not been publicly released.

The video begins with Ms. Pelosi speaking about guidance to the Capitol Police: “We asked them to put out a piece of paper saying, ‘Go through the tunnel. Don’t go outside.’ They say they’ve got stuff, but they can’t tell us what it is. It’s too — we don’t want the other side to know. We have responsibility, Terry, we didn’t have accountability for what was going on there.”

When the person Ms. Pelosi was addressing responded, “they thought they had sufficient resources,” Ms. Pelosi cut her off. “It’s not a question of sufficient,” the speaker said, “they don’t know. They clearly didn’t know, and I take responsibility for not having them prepare for me, because it’s stupid because we’re in a situation like this.”

Politico reviewed roughly 45 minutes of footage and concluded that it “does not bolster G.O.P. claims” of Ms. Pelosi being at fault.

Lisa Friedman

Lisa Friedman

“The Paris accord was going to cost us $1 trillion and China, nothing, and Russia, nothing, and India, nothing.”

This is misleading ..

Under the Paris agreement, a voluntary global climate accord, wealthier nations agreed to help poor countries most threatened by climate change. Under President Biden, the United States has pledged $11.4 billion annually by 2024 to assist vulnerable countries in developing clean energy and preparing for the consequences of climate change.

China also contributes to developing countries, albeit not through the U.N., but through a separate “South-South” cooperation fund. The United States, under the Biden administration, has been pressuring China to donate more.

Jeanna Smialek

Jeanna Smialek

“You look at the cost of food, where it’s doubled and tripled and quadrupled.”

Grocery prices are up significantly since early 2021, but they have not doubled, tripled or quadrupled overall because of inflation. The “food at home” inflation index that tracks grocery prices is up about 20 percent since then, for instance.

Noah Weiland

Noah Weiland

“I’m the one that got the insulin down for the seniors.”

Mr. Trump established a voluntary $35-per-month cap on insulin costs for Medicare beneficiaries, something only a limited number of Medicare plans participated in.

The Inflation Reduction Act, signed by President Biden in 2022, required plans to cap insulin costs at $35 each month, increasing the number of Medicare beneficiaries who would be covered by the policy. Mr. Biden has pushed to make the cap applicable to people with commercial insurance, a provision that was removed from the Inflation Reduction Act before it became law.

Coral Davenport

Coral Davenport

“During my four years, I had the best environmental numbers ever.”

Mr. Trump responded to a question about what he might do in response to climate change by saying that his administration rolled back nearly 100 environmental regulations, including protections on clean air and clean water.

In terms of numbers, the United States’ carbon dioxide emissions stayed at roughly the same levels from 2017, the first year of Mr. Trump’s administration, through 2019, before declining sharply in 2020 due to the impacts of the Covid-19 pandemic on travel and economic activity.

Angelo Fichera

Angelo Fichera

“And what he’s done to the Black population is horrible, including the fact that for 10 years he called them superpredators.”

Mr. Trump has previously made this claim about Mr. Biden, including at an October 2020 debate . But it was Mr. Trump’s 2016 political rival, Hillary Clinton, the former secretary of state, who once used that term — not Mr. Biden.

In 1996, Ms. Clinton, then the first lady, said at a campaign event: “They are often connected to big drug cartels; they are not just gangs of kids anymore. They are often the kinds of kids that are called superpredators. No conscience, no empathy. We can talk about why they ended up that way, but first we have to bring them to heel.”

Ms. Clinton spoke at that event in support of a 1994 crime bill that Mr. Biden had also supported at the time — and that experts later found contributed to the mass incarceration that hurt Black communities. Mr. Biden apologized in 2019 for parts of his anti-crime legislation, but also tried to downplay his involvement.

“Even from a medical standpoint, right to try: where we can try space-age materials instead of going to Asia or going to Europe and trying to get, when you’re terminally ill, now you can go and you can get something, you sign a document. They’ve been trying to get it for 42 years. But you know, what we did for the military was incredible, choice for our soldiers, where our soldiers, instead of waiting for three months to see a doctor, can go out and get themselves fixed up and readied up, and take care of themselves. And they’re living and that’s why I had the highest approval rating of the history of the V.A.”

The Veterans Choice health care program was created in 2014 ; Mr. Trump signed an update to that law. Similarly, the “right to try” law of 2018 allows terminally ill patients to seek access to experimental medicine that is not yet fully approved by the Food and Drug Administration, but a similar program has been in place since the 1970s.

“The only jobs he created are for illegal immigrants.”

Official estimates of employment do not support Mr. Trump’s statement. And estimates from various groups show that the population of unauthorized immigrants has grown in recent years, but not nearly enough to take all the jobs created under President Biden.

The economy has added more than 15 million jobs since January 2021. Two groups that advocate lower levels of migration and stricter border security have estimated that there are 2.3 million to 2.5 million more unauthorized immigrants in 2023 than in 2020.

Overall, the Bureau of Labor Statistics estimated that 29.9 million foreign-born workers — both authorized and unauthorized — and 131.1 million native-born workers were employed in 2023. That is an increase of 5.1 million in employed foreign-born workers and 8.1 million native-born workers since 2020 .

“No indictments, no political opponents stuff, because it’s the only way he thinks he can win.”

This lacks evidence..

Mr. Trump has claimed repeatedly that his numerous legal woes were orchestrated by President Biden. Of the four criminal cases against Mr. Trump, two were brought by state or local prosecutors, meaning that the Justice Department itself has no control over them.

The other two criminal cases against Mr. Trump are overseen by a special counsel, whom Attorney General Merrick B. Garland appointed to avoid the appearance of a conflict of interest. There is no evidence that Mr. Biden is personally directing the cases against his political opponent. Mr. Biden has publicly emphasized the independence of the Justice Department.

“It’s not only the 18 million people that I believe is even low because they, the gotaways — they don’t even talk about gotaways.”

It is impossible to know the exact number of migrants that have entered the United States, but Mr. Trump’s estimate is hyperbolic.

Since February 2021, the first full month of Mr. Biden’s presidency, Customs and Border Protection has recorded 9.6 million migrant encounters nationwide , including about 7.9 million at the southwestern border. This does not necessarily mean that nearly 10 million migrants have attempted to enter the country, as one migrant can be encountered multiple times. Government and independent analyses have estimated that repeat offenders account for a quarter to more than half of all encounters.

Many other migrants have evaded capture, but the exact number is unclear. Republicans have previously cited one estimate obtained by Fox News: about 1.6 million migrants since 2021.

But more than four million migrants have also been turned away or deported under Mr. Biden. About three million were quickly expelled under a public health law, were placed into “expedited removal” proceedings or left voluntarily.

“We have the largest deficit with China.”

The U.S. trade deficit with China in goods and services was $252 billion last year, the lowest level since 2009.

Kenneth P. Vogel

Kenneth P. Vogel

“He gets paid by China.”

— Former President Donald J. Trump.

Mr. Trump was referring to President Biden and appeared to be nodding to payments from a company called C.E.F.C. China Energy and its affiliates to entities associated with Mr. Biden’s son Hunter and his brother James.

No evidence has emerged that any portion of these payments, which started after Mr. Biden left the vice presidency, went to Joseph R. Biden Jr.

Ben Protess

Ben Protess

“He basically went after his political opponent because he thought it was going to damage me.”

Mr. Trump’s claim that President Biden orchestrated his conviction has no basis in fact. The investigation began while Mr. Trump, not Mr. Biden, was president. The case was brought by the Manhattan district attorney, Alvin L. Bragg, a local Democrat who does not answer to Mr. Biden’s administration. And Mr. Trump was convicted by a jury of 12 New Yorkers.

“He caused this inflation.”

Independent economic research has found that government stimulus spending approved by both Mr. Trump and Mr. Biden contributed to the soaring inflation the nation experienced in the first two years of Mr. Biden’s presidency. But no evidence blames government spending, by Mr. Biden or Mr. Trump, for the majority of the inflation the country experienced.

A 2023 research paper by the economists Ben S. Bernanke and Olivier Blanchard found “most of the rise in inflation in 2021 and 2022 was driven by developments that directly raised prices rather than wages, including sharp increases in global commodity prices and sectoral price spikes driven by a combination of pandemic-induced kinks in supply chains and a huge shift in demand during the pandemic to goods from services.”

“They moved a high-ranking official, a D.O.J., into the Manhattan D.A.’s office to start that case.”

Mr. Trump regularly claims that a Justice Department official from the Biden administration was the driving force behind his recent criminal conviction in Manhattan. In fact, the investigation into Mr. Trump had begun years before that former Justice Department official even joined the Manhattan district attorney’s office.

The former official was one of several prosecutors to work on the case, which recently ended with Mr. Trump’s conviction on 34 felony charges of falsifying business records. But the district attorney, Alvin L. Bragg, was responsible for bringing the case.

Hamed Aleaziz

Hamed Aleaziz

“What I’ve done, since I’ve changed the law, what’s happened? I’ve changed it in a way that now you’re in a situation where there are 40 percent fewer people coming across the border illegally. It’s better than when he left office.”

— President Biden

The number of daily encounters at the southern border has dropped 40 percent since a Biden administration measure essentially banning asylum took effect in early June, but border crossings were generally lower during the Trump administration.

“Black unemployment is the lowest level it’s been in a long, long time.”

Unemployment is relatively low for Black workers today by historical standards, although that was also true before the onset of the pandemic in 2019.

Miriam Jordan

Miriam Jordan

“And because of his ridiculous, insane and very stupid policies, people are coming in and killing our citizens at a level we’ve never — we call it migrant crime. I’d call it Biden-migrant crime.”

While there have been highly publicized cases of Americans killed by undocumented immigrants, these cases do not represent a broader trend. Numerous studies have found that immigration does not push up crime rates. Immigrants are less likely to commit crimes and less likely to be incarcerated than American citizens.

“We have the largest number of terrorists coming into our country right now. All terrorists, all over the world, not just in South America, all over the world. They come from the Middle East, everywhere, all over the world. They’re pouring in. And this guy just left it open.”

The number of people trying to illegally cross the southern border whose names match those on the United States’ terrorist watch list has indeed risen in recent years . Still, those numbers are a very small percentage of total Border Patrol encounters — 0.0083 percent in the 2023 fiscal year between the northern and southern border — and what that means in terms of the terrorist threat to the United States is not entirely clear.

The watch list includes names of known and suspected terrorists, as well as people affiliated with them; the database has not been without criticism for how it is managed.

In the 2023 fiscal year, 169 noncitizens whose names appeared on the list tried to illegally cross the southern border — up from three such encounters in the 2020 fiscal year — according to Customs and Border Protection statistics . So far in the 2024 fiscal year, there have been 90 instances of those encounters. (More people with names appearing on the list have presented at legal ports of entry, especially at the northern border.)

There is no record of a terrorist attack committed on American soil by an immigrant who crossed the southern border illegally.

“He did nothing to stop it. In fact, I think he encouraged Russia from going in.”

— Former President Donald J. Trump, referring to the Biden administration’s response to Russia’s preparation to invade Ukraine

This is false.

The Biden administration sent William J. Burns, the C.I.A. director, to Russia in November 2021 to tell President Vladimir V. Putin that U.S. intelligence knew of his plans to invade Ukraine and warn him not to invade. President Biden also declassified intelligence about Russia’s plans to invade Ukraine in an effort to dissuade Russia from invading and rally allied support for Ukraine.

Mr. Biden threatened — and wound up imposing — vast economic sanctions against Russia’s economy and political leadership.

“I made great trade deals with the European nations.”

Mr. Trump engaged in trade negotiations with the European Union during his presidency and the talks culminated in a limited agreement in August 2020. That deal was much smaller than what people typically refer to as a trade deal, and it did not shift the balance of trade in the United States’ favor. The U.S. trade deficit in goods and services with the European Union grew steadily over Mr. Trump’s term to $146 billion in 2021 when he left office, up from $89 billion in 2017.

“He decided to open up our border.”

The number of migrants who have crossed the border illegally has skyrocketed under the Biden administration. Migrants have come to the southern border for a number of reasons, including fleeing collapsing governments, and the Biden administration initially took a softer tone on the border, including rolling back some policies set by Mr. Trump.

But President Biden kept in place a Trump-era policy to turn back migrants quickly at the southern border after he took over.

And in the last year, the Biden administration has put in place restrictions on asylum, including a recent effort to ban it for people who cross illegally.

“51 intelligence agents said that the laptop was Russia disinformation. It wasn’t. That came from his son Hunter. It wasn’t Russia disinformation.”

— Former President Donald J. Trump, on Hunter Biden’s recovered computer.

This needs more context.

Mr. Trump is referring to efforts by President Biden’s allies to cast doubt on the authenticity of the contents of a laptop belonging to his son, Hunter Biden, that was left at a repair shop in Wilmington, Del.

The laptop contained a cache of files that shed light on Hunter Biden’s foreign business dealings, as well as embarrassing information about his behavior during a time when he was in the throes of addiction. The contents of the laptop were provided in 2020 to Rudolph W. Giuliani, who was serving as Mr. Trump’s lawyer. Mr. Giuliani, in turn, provided the contents to The New York Post, which published the first in a series of articles relying on material from the laptop on Oct. 14, 2020, less than a month before the presidential election.

The story prompted immediate backlash. Prompted by outreach from Antony J. Blinken, who was then serving as a Biden campaign adviser, a group of former intelligence officials drafted and signed a letter calling into question the underlying files, claiming they had “the classic earmarks of a Russian information operation.” While the letter stopped short of claiming Russian involvement, emails subsequently released by House Republicans show that the people behind it wanted to create the impression that “the Russians are interfering.”

A few days later, at a presidential debate with Mr. Trump, Joseph R. Biden Jr. cited the letter as evidence that the laptop was “a Russian plant” and “a bunch of garbage.”

Nearly three years later, no evidence has emerged to support assertions that Russia was involved in the laptop’s contents or its dissemination, and many of the emails contained on it have been authenticated by the news media through forensic analysis and interviews .

David E. Sanger

David E. Sanger

“Iran was broke with me. I wouldn’t let anybody do business with them. They ran out of money. They were broke, they had no money for Hamas. They had no money for anything, no money for terror.”

Even under sanctions that were imposed by the Trump administration, Iran’s economy plugged along. It wasn’t strong, but it wasn’t broke, and it kept trading with many nations. Mr. Trump made no mention of the fact that his withdrawal from an Obama-era nuclear deal freed Iran to resume nuclear production.

Michael Crowley

Michael Crowley

“We’re no longer respected as a country. They don’t respect our leadership. They don’t respect the United States anymore.”

The concept of international “respect” can be subjective, but what hard data exists shows that President Biden enjoys more approval overseas than does Mr. Trump.

The latest international poll conducted by the Pew Research Center , released earlier this month, found that “Biden is viewed more positively than his rival.” In a poll of citizens in 34 countries, 43 percent said they have confidence in Mr. Biden “to do the right thing regarding world affairs,” while just 28 percent said the same thing about Mr. Trump. In 24 of those countries, Pew found, Mr. Biden rated at least five points higher than did Mr. Trump. Mr. Trump fared better in only two: Tunisia and Hungary.

Kate Zernike

Kate Zernike

“They will take the life of a child in the eighth month, ninth month, even after birth.”

Mr. Trump was describing the Biden administration’s approach to abortion policy.

Abortion “after birth” would be infanticide, which is illegal in every state. And abortions late in pregnancy are very rare: In 2021, less than 1 percent of abortions happened after 21 weeks’ gestation, according to Centers for Disease Control and Prevention statistics collected from state and other health agencies. More than 90 percent of abortions happened within 13 weeks of pregnancy, which is dated to the start of a woman’s last monthly period.

“I went to the World War II cemetery — World War I cemetery he refused to go to. He was standing with his four-star general, and he told me he said, ‘I don’t want to go in there because they’re a bunch of losers and suckers.’”

The quotes “losers” and “suckers” originate from an article published in The Atlantic in 2020 about former President Donald J. Trump’s relationship to the military. He continues to dispute the reports.

The article relied on anonymous sources, but many of the accounts have been corroborated by news outlets, including The New York Times , and by John F. Kelly, a retired four-star Marine general who was Mr. Trump’s White House chief of staff. Mr. Trump has emphatically denied making the remarks since the Atlantic article was published.

Here is a breakdown of the quotations.

“Just take a look at where they are living. They are living in luxury hotels in New York City and other places.”

Tens of thousands of migrants who crossed the border into the United States were offered free bus rides to Democratic cities under a program started by Gov. Greg Abbott of Texas in an attempt to spread the burden of the large influx. Some cities, like New York and Denver, have housed migrants in hotels, especially during the winter months. The migrants were not in luxury hotels.

Elizabeth Dias

Elizabeth Dias

“Every legal scholar wanted it that way.”

— Former President Donald J. Trump, referring to the Supreme Court’s decision to overturn Roe v. Wade two years ago

Three Supreme Court justices dissented in the landmark ruling in 2022, and abortion rights remain broadly popular. A majority of Americans disapprove of the Supreme Court’s decision to overturn Roe, according to the Pew Research Center . Extensive polling also shows that public opinion increasingly supports legal abortion since the ruling.

Emiliano Rodríguez Mega

Emiliano Rodríguez Mega

“Mexico is working with us to make sure they don’t have the technology to be able to put it together.”

— President Biden on efforts to combat drug trafficking

It was unclear what Mr. Biden meant exactly by this statement. But the United States and Mexican officials indeed have increased their cooperation to counter drug trafficking in recent years.

Mexico, for instance, enacted a new law to detect and punish illicit synthetic drug production, dedicated federal prosecutors to work on fentanyl cases, extradited a fentanyl trafficker, Ovidio Guzmán, to the United States and is expected to acquire scanning technology to screen for fentanyl. The U.S. government has also provided training for Mexican coroners to better identify fentanyl overdoses.

“He wants to get rid of Social Security. He thinks that there’s plenty to cut in Social Security. He’s wanted to cut Social Security and Medicare both times.”

Mr. Trump has repeatedly vowed during this campaign to protect Social Security and Medicare. But Mr. Biden and his campaign have at times homed in on select comments in which Mr. Trump appeared to suggest that he would be open to cuts — such as a remark Mr. Trump made during an interview in March — while ignoring clarifications.

Asked about his position on the programs in relation to the national debt, Mr. Trump told CNBC in March: “There is a lot you can do in terms of entitlements in terms of cutting and in terms of also the theft and the bad management of entitlements.”

Mr. Trump and his campaign quickly clarified , however, that he would not seek to cut the programs. “I will never do anything that will jeopardize or hurt Social Security or Medicare,” Mr. Trump told the conservative website Breitbart . “We’ll have to do it elsewhere. But we’re not going to do anything to hurt them.”

Mr. Trump also said in a video posted to his social media platform last year that “under no circumstances should Republicans vote to cut a single penny from Medicare or Social Security.”

Still, Mr. Trump has not outlined a clear plan for keeping the programs solvent.

During his time in office, Mr. Trump did propose some cuts to Medicare — though experts said the cost reductions would not have significantly affected benefits — and to Social Security’s programs for people with disabilities. They were not enacted by Congress.

“He wants to get rid of the A.C.A. again, and they’re going to try again.”

Mr. Trump campaigned in 2016 on repealing and replacing the Affordable Care Act, but Republicans in Congress failed to do so. Though Mr. Trump continues to criticize the health care law as an expensive “disaster,” he has recently suggested he would improve it rather than repeal the law altogether.

In a January rally in Iowa , Mr. Trump promised “much better health care at a lower price for you, and that will be either working on Obamacare or doing something new.”

“ I’m not running to terminate the ACA ,” Mr. Trump wrote on social media in March, adding that he was running to make the health care law “much, much, much better for far less money.”

Mr. Trump has not released any specific details on what this would entail. On his campaign website, he pledged to “stop all Covid mandates and restore medical freedom, end surprise medical billing, increase fairness through price transparency, and further reduce the cost of prescription drugs and health insurance premiums” and also to protect “patients with pre-existing conditions.”

“They’re taking Black jobs and they’re taking Hispanic jobs. And you haven’t seen it yet.”

Whether or not immigrants depress wages or displace some workers has been examined by economists for decades, and there is no clear conclusion. Indeed, a few studies have shown negative wage effects, particularly on African American workers and other Americans in occupations in which there are many Latino immigrants.

Several studies have found a mutually beneficial relationship between high-skilled immigrants and similarly skilled natives, as well as between low-skilled immigrants and more highly skilled native workers, contributes to higher wages for natives. They have also found that immigrants are an increasingly important part of the U.S. labor force as more Americans age and exit the work force.

Alexandra Berzon

Alexandra Berzon

“The fraud and everything else was ridiculous.”

— Former President Donald J. Trump, referring to the 2020 election

The Associated Press combed through potential cases of fraud in battleground states during the 2020 election and came away with 475 possible cases of voter fraud. That is far less than the hundreds of thousands of falsely counted or changed votes claimed by Mr. Trump and his associates and supporters.

It is also a minuscule amount compared with the more than 300,000 votes that separated Mr. Biden from Mr. Trump in the close states of Pennsylvania, Arizona, Wisconsin, Nevada, Georgia and Michigan.

In addition, independent studies, including from conservative elections legal experts and academics, as well as local, federal and state investigations and audits and judges across the country, have closely examined and dismissed the claims put forth by Mr. Trump and his supporters.

“He allowed millions of people to come in here from prisons, jails, and mental institutions — to come into our country and destroy our country.”

Mr. Trump has not provided any evidence for this claim, and immigration experts have said that they could not corroborate Mr. Trump’s claims .

The Trump campaign has previously cited an article published in September 2022 on Breitbart, a conservative website. One unnamed source told Breitbart that officials believed that an unspecified number of Venezuelan prison inmates were headed for the United States’ southern border with Mexico. (No other news organization or government source has verified this report.) The Trump campaign also pointed to reports warning that Tren de Aragua, a transnational criminal gang founded in Venezuela, was growing in the United States.

There is no evidence that “millions” of criminals are infiltrating the southern border. Customs and Border Protection reported apprehending 47 members of Tren de Aragua along the southern border under President Biden.

Abbie VanSickle

Abbie VanSickle

“First of all, the Supreme Court just approved the abortion pill, and I agree with the decision to have done that. And I will not block it.”

Mr. Trump is correct that the practical effect of the Supreme Court’s decision was that the justices maintained broad access to the abortion pill. However, the justices did not “approve” the drug. The court declined to rule on the merits of the case.

In a unanimous decision , the court held that the anti-abortion groups lacked a direct stake in the dispute, a requirement to challenge the Food and Drug Administration’s approval of the pill, mifepristone.

“More people died under his administration — even though we had largely fixed it — more people died under his administration than our administration, and we were right in the middle of it.”

Around 450,000 people in the United States had died of Covid-19 by the time Mr. Trump left office, less than a year into the pandemic. More than 1.1 million people had died from the virus by this month, according to the Centers for Disease Control and Prevention, meaning more people did in fact die during Mr. Biden’s first term.

Mr. Biden took office during a winter wave of cases, and the virus continued to change in substantial ways after Mr. Trump left office, spawning new, deadly, highly transmissible variants that remained fatal to many Americans for years to come.

“This is something that everybody wanted.”

Mr. Trump was referring to the Supreme Court’s decision two years ago to overturn Roe v. Wade, which had established a constitutional right to abortion. Polls show that the overwhelming majority of Americans continue to disagree with that decision.

“We have 1,000 trillionaires in America — I mean billionaires in America — and what’s happening, they’re in a situation where they in fact pay 8.2 percent in taxes.”

Mr. Biden is referring to a White House study, released in 2021 , that used a “more comprehensive measure of income” than is currently assessed.

The report in question included gains made in unsold stocks, which are not taxed until the asset is sold. It estimated that the average federal income tax rate paid by the 400 wealthiest families in the United States to be 8.2 percent.

Under the law now, the top 1 percent of earners in the United States are currently estimated to pay an average federal income tax rate of more than 20 percent, according to an analysis published by the Treasury Department in November.

The White House has argued that its report presents a more accurate view of the tax rate paid by the wealthy.

“Not going to drive them higher.”

— Former President Donald J. Trump on whether tariffs would increase prices

Tariffs are designed to protect domestic industries by raising the price of foreign products, and economists anticipate that any increase in tariffs would result in some increase in prices.

Economic studies found that the tariffs that Mr. Trump imposed on Chinese goods during his first term were largely paid by American consumers, rather than Chinese companies. In a recent letter, 16 Nobel Prize-winning economists wrote that there was concern that Trump’s policies, including his plan to impose blanket tariffs on most imports, would reignite inflation.

“He’s destroying Medicare because all of these people are coming in. They’re putting them on Medicare. They’re putting them on Social Security. They’re going to destroy Social Security. This man is going to single-handedly destroy Social Security.”

Unauthorized immigrants actually improve the financial health of both Social Security and Medicare. Federal law bars them from receiving Social Security or Medicare benefits, but they pay into both programs. In a 2013 report, the Social Security Administration estimated that 3.1 million unauthorized immigrants were working and paying Social Security taxes. They contributed about $12 billion to the trust in 2010 and about $100 billion over a decade. A 2016 study estimated that unauthorized immigrants contributed about $35.1 billion to Medicare from 2000 to 2011.

And Mr. Biden has proposed plans to shore up Social Security and has vowed for years not to cut the program. During the 2020 campaign, Mr. Biden proposed increasing taxes on high-income earners to pay for additional Social Security benefits and reduce the program’s financial shortfall. This election cycle, Mr. Biden has also said he would raise taxes on the wealthy, make no cuts to the program and opposes raising the retirement age.

“The economy collapsed, there were no jobs.”

Mr. Biden said that he inherited a broken economy when he took office. While employment collapsed at the onset of the pandemic in 2020, jobs had begun to bounce back rapidly relatively quickly, and the recovery was well underway by the time Mr. Biden took office in early 2021.

“The tax cuts spurred the greatest economy that we’ve ever seen.”

Economic research suggests that the tax cut Mr. Trump signed in 2017 spurred some additional economic growth and income growth, but nowhere close to what Mr. Trump and Republicans promised.

Researchers from Princeton University, the University of Chicago, Harvard University and the Treasury Department found in an analysis this year that the cuts delivered wage gains that were “an order of magnitude below” what Trump officials predicted: About $750 per worker per year on average over the long run, compared to promises of $4,000 to $9,000 per worker.

“I was getting out of Afghanistan.”

It is certainly true that Mr. Trump often said, in the 2016 campaign, that he wanted to pull American troops out of Afghanistan. But at the end of his presidency, a small force remained, and while he said on social media that all forces should be home by Christmas 2020, he never executed on that promise. President Biden did pull them out. But it was poorly executed.

“He’s the only president other than Herbert Hoover who’s lost more jobs than he had when he began.”

Mr. Biden is accurate that former President Donald J. Trump is the only president since World War II to leave office with a negative jobs record, but he did not make clear that this occurred, of course, because of the coronavirus pandemic.

Using January 2017 as a base line, when Mr. Trump was inaugurated, there were 145.6 million jobs, according to Bureau of Labor Statistics data . When he left in January 2021, there were 142.9 million jobs. That is a decline of 2.7 million jobs, or 1.9 percent.

But before the pandemic took hold, jobs had increased under Mr. Trump’s tenure, from 145.6 million jobs in January 2017 to 152 million jobs in January 2020 — a rise of 6.4 million jobs, or 4.4 percent.

About half of the nearly 22 million jobs lost in early 2020 were recovered before Mr. Trump left office.

The same data from the Bureau of Labor Statistics goes back only to 1939, several years after Mr. Hoover departed the White House in 1933. But Mr. Hoover was president at the start of the Great Depression, and when he left office, nearly a quarter of the labor force was unemployed.

“The jobs went down, and then they bounced back. And he’s taking credit for bounce-back jobs.”

The economy has added more than 15 million jobs since Mr. Biden took office in January 2021, but it is true that some of that has been a bounce back from a sharp drop in employment during the pandemic.

That said, employment has now completely recovered to where it would have been had the pace of hiring that prevailed in the year leading up to the pandemic held steady, and employment growth has remained robust. In fact, the pace of job gains has surprised many economists, regularly beating expectations.

“I gave you the largest cut in history.”

The $1.5 trillion tax cut, enacted in December 2017, ranks below at least half a dozen others by several metrics. The 1981 tax cut enacted under President Ronald Reagan is the largest as a percentage of the economy and by its reduction to federal revenue. The 2012 cut enacted under President Barack Obama amounted to the largest cut in inflation-adjusted dollars: $321 billion a year.

“The economy collapsed. There were no jobs.”

— President Biden, on what he inherited from the Trump administration upon coming into office

While employment collapsed at the onset of the pandemic in 2020, jobs began to bounce back rapidly relatively quickly, and the recovery was well underway by the time President Biden took office in early 2021.

“All he said was, ‘It’s not that serious, just inject a little bleach in your arm.’”

Mr. Trump’s comments, in April 2020, about the efficacy of disinfectants and light as treatments for the coronavirus prompted uproar and confusion . He did not literally instruct people to drink bleach, but raised the suggestion as an “interesting” concept to test out.

At the April 2020 news conference, a member of Mr. Trump’s coronavirus task force said that the virus dies under direct sunlight and that applying bleach in indoor spaces kills the virus in five minutes and isopropyl alcohol in 30 seconds.

Mr. Trump responded: “Supposing we hit the body with a tremendous — whether it’s ultraviolet or just very powerful light — and I think you said that that hasn’t been checked, but you’re going to test it. And then I said, supposing you brought the light inside the body, which you can do either through the skin or in some other way, and I think you said you’re going to test that too.

“And then I see the disinfectant, where it knocks it out in a minute. One minute. And is there a way we can do something like that, by injection inside or almost a cleaning. Because you see it gets in the lungs and it does a tremendous number on the lungs. So it would be interesting to check that,” he said.

IMAGES

  1. (PDF) Litigating Economic Sanctions

    economic sanctions thesis

  2. Economic Sanctions in International Relations

    economic sanctions thesis

  3. PPT

    economic sanctions thesis

  4. Perfect overview on economic sanctions

    economic sanctions thesis

  5. Economic sanctions and their impact on international trade

    economic sanctions thesis

  6. Comprehensive Economic Sanctions, the Right to Development, and

    economic sanctions thesis

VIDEO

  1. Unmasking E Banking Fraud in The Nigerian Financial System

  2. Lyn Alden’s 2024 Investment Thesis: “Nothing Stops This Train”

COMMENTS

  1. It S Not That Simple: Examining the Nuance of Economic Sanctions

    Unlike much of the existing literature on economic sanctions, this thesis subscribes to neither a sanctions-optimist nor a sanctions-pessimist perspective. Rather, it emphasizes that irrespective of whether the intended policy objective of a sanctions regime is achieved, it is possible for conditions to be created through sanctions imposition ...

  2. Analyzing the effects of economic sanctions: Recent theory, data, and

    Evolution of economic sanctions, 1950-2022. This figure is from Syropoulos et al. from this issue.The figure illustrates the number of all active sanctions (dark solid line), all pre-existing minus terminated sanctions (blue dashed line), and newly imposed sanctions (red solid line, which is equivalent to the distance between the dark solid and blue dashed lines) in each year between 1950 ...

  3. PDF Economic sanctions: a tool of the past or the future?

    In order to gain a better understanding of the effects of economic sanctions I study the effect that sanction episodes in the period of 1962 till 2000 have had on international trade. ... Sanctions in the context of this thesis are defined as: Measures taken by a state to coerce another to conform to an international agreement or norms of ...

  4. Economic Sanctions' Effectiveness in a World with Interdependent

    on Economic Statecraft spurred my interest in economic sanctions and helped me narrow the focus of this thesis. Dr. Doherty-Sil also gave me invaluable assistance and contributed to make this thesis possible, from discussing the initial proposal, to leading the thesis seminar, to providing reassurance during the final weeks.

  5. PDF The Role of Third Countries in the Effectiveness of Economic Sanctions

    The subject of sanctions is significant and covers different disciplines, including economics, international relations, and politics. This thesis will focus on economic sanctions that concern trade and financial instruments. Sanctions with more diplomatic, military, or social characteristics will not be covered by this thesis.

  6. PDF THE IMPACT OF ECONOMIC SANCTIONS

    The third chapter tests the main hypothesis of the thesis: when economic sanctions are imposed, there is a reaction in the FDI stock of the United States (US) in the target countries. In the analysis, economic sanctions between 2000-2017 are investigated, and 54 countries with available data are selected for close scrutiny.

  7. Consequences of Economic Sanctions: The State of the Art and Paths

    We consider third-party states, or states not participating in sanctions or involuntarily taking part in their enforcement (for example, in the mandatory United Nations sanctions) because the increasing use of secondary or extraterritorial sanctions limiting the economic activities of third-state actors with "primary targets" (Meyer 2009 ...

  8. (PDF) ECONOMIC SANCTIONS: THEORY, POLICY, MECHANISMS

    Economic sanctions are the integral part of international. economic policy, implemented through the theory of public (rational) choice, structural theory (cost-issue model), decision-making theory ...

  9. PDF Economic Sanctions and Human Rights: Quantifying the Legal

    17. sanctions, such as unilateral versus multilateral sanctions, and targeted ver-sus non-targeted sanctions. After combining the data on economic sanctions with the smaller human rights dataset, 235 country-year observations with U.S. sanctions remain.

  10. Economic sanctions, repression capacity, and human rights

    His Master's thesis, "Can Middle Powers Coerce? Behavioral Patterns in Economic Sanctions after Cold War" empirically assesses the effect of middle power on international economic sanctions. Taehee Whang. Taehee Whang is a Professor of Political Science and International Studies, Yonsei University. After receiving a PhD from the ...

  11. PDF ECONOMIC SANCTIONS AND AUTOCRATIC REPRESSION A Thesis

    In "Economic Sanctions Reconsidered" the authors claim that in some instances sanctions are successful (and they even suggest "do" and "don'ts" to enhance the chances of success). On the other hand Robert A. Pape claims economic sanctions do not achieve the objectives for which they were put in place (Pape. 1998, 66-77). A ...

  12. Essays on Economic Sanctions

    Essays on Economic Sanctions. Authors. Walsh, William. Issue Date 2018-07. Type. Thesis or Dissertation. Abstract. Do economic sanctions impact the economy on a macro level? I address this question using Iran as a case study. Over the last 20 years, the share of Iran's total trade with western developed economies has declined. Like most other ...

  13. PDF The Impact of Economic Sanctions on International Trade: How do

    the threatening stage is critically releanvt in understanding the outcome of sanctions and the threat of economic sanctions may even be more important than the actual imposition (Eaton & Engers,1992 ;Lacy & Niou,2004). There are also studies that attribute the general conclusion of sanctions being ine ective to the exclusion of the

  14. PDF Studying Economic Sanctions using the Graph Model for Conflict Resolution

    The main contributions put forward in this thesis are: the introduction of a two identical Graph Model. system with different preferences to illustrate the strength of sanctions, the use of BATNA to guide a. DM into making an informed choice, and the employment of CT to reduce the size of the conflict. model.

  15. The Effectiveness of Economic Sanctions: A Literature Review

    In a wide range, economic sanctions concern the ca tegories of. international trade, justice a nd, to a certain extent, also stability. In the context of this essay, the de nition of the term "e ...

  16. PDF Bachelor thesis Economic effects of international sanctions: The

    ell while taking to significant damage from the imposed sanctions against Russia. The country t. at had the most obvious economic effects from international sanctions was Russia. The combination of the import ban, the financial sanctions, and the drop in the oil price resulted in a devastating currency crisis for Russ.

  17. PDF Economic Sanctions: Embargo on Stage. Theory and Empirical Evidence.

    wever, economic sanctions imply costs, especially in terms of trade. This thesis provides an overview of the literature on this topic, in describing the historical and institutional law framewor. of economic sanctions and in presenting models and empirical works. The first part describes the history, the institution.

  18. An ethics of economic sanctions

    Some common means of economic warfare are trade embargoes, boycotts, sanctions, tariff discrimination, the freezing of capital assets, the suspension of aid, the prohibition of investment and other capital flows, and expropriation. (Shambaugh) This definition presents economic sanctions as a tool by which economic warfare is.

  19. PDF Sanctions, what sanctions?

    effectiveness of sanctions topical. We will in this thesis investigate the impacts sanctions have onRussia's total trade. The aim of the thesis is to examine the causal effects on Russia's trade following the 2014 sanctions until 2019. The armed conflict in Ukraine started in 2014 in conjunction with Russia's annexation of Crimea.

  20. Dissertation or Thesis

    Hungary's economic relationship with the European Union is one that may be characterized by asymmetrical interdependence. Recent events in Hungary suggest an advance of illiberal governance practices in Hungary, which would contradict with stated EU interests in promoting liberal democracy and rule of law.

  21. PDF The Power of Economic Sanctions with Application to the case ...

    pean Union appointed economic sanctions in July 2014 and added new sanctions in Sep-tember 2014 again. In March 2015, the European Council associated the period of those ... The aim of the thesis research is to measure the influence of sanctions on the banking sector of Russia. To accomplish this aim following tasks should be decided:

  22. Economic Sanctions Disruption on International Trade Patterns and

    Abstract. Governments frequently use economic sanctions to influence or undermine the political actions or regimes of other countries. This case study of the economic sanctions imposed by the European Union on the Russian Federation in response to the annexation of the Crimean Peninsula serves as an illustrative example that provides new, in-depth insights into the implications of economic ...

  23. "An ethics of economic sanctions" by Macallee N. Goldman

    Goldman, Macallee N., "An ethics of economic sanctions" (2016). Honors Theses. This paper provides an ethical analysis of smart sanctions under the combined framework of the categorical imperative and utilitarianism. Developing an ethical model that also encompasses sanction effectiveness as a means of evaluation, this paper argues that smart ...

  24. Economists reveal the costs of sanctions

    Economic sanctions can be a double-edged sword. On the one hand, they usually reduce gross domestic product and thus prosperity in the affected countries, as intended. On the other hand, however ...

  25. Debate Fact Check: Biden and Trump on the Economy, Immigration and

    Economic research suggests that the tax cut Mr. Trump signed in 2017 spurred some additional economic growth and income growth, but nowhere close to what Mr. Trump and Republicans promised.