Pecking Order Theory and Innovativeness of Companies

  • Conference paper
  • First Online: 28 December 2016
  • Cite this conference paper

thesis pecking order

  • Katarzyna Prędkiewicz 2 &
  • Paweł Prędkiewicz 3  

Part of the book series: Springer Proceedings in Business and Economics ((SPBE))

2658 Accesses

1 Citations

The purpose of this paper is to explore whether the “pecking order hypothesis” applies to the capital finance preferences of innovative companies. The research is based on a survey of 409 companies. We asked them about attitude towards innovation—three answers were possible (neutral, innovation “on occasion” and pro-innovative attitude) and to indicate the financing hierarchy for five sources of capital (retained earnings, bank credit or loan, additional capital from the current owners, loan from the owners and new external equity capital). We found that in general, the hierarchy is consistent with the pecking order theory. On the first place with the higher frequency, retained earnings were pointed out, on the second place—bank credit or loan, and on the last (fifth)—new external equity. Innovativeness of companies changes the hierarchy of financing in the third and fourth place. Innovative companies after retained earnings and bank loans prefer loans from the owners, whereas companies with neutral attitude towards innovation, additional capital from the current owners. Moreover, the group that describes their attitude towards innovations as “innovation on occasion” is the most diverse in their preferences, whereas the group with “pro-innovative” strategy has consistent preferences.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Subscribe and save.

  • Get 10 units per month
  • Download Article/Chapter or eBook
  • 1 Unit = 1 Article or 1 Chapter
  • Cancel anytime
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
  • Durable hardcover edition

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Similar content being viewed by others

thesis pecking order

The Main Factors that Determine the Company’s Innovations–Empirical Research of Companies in Serbia

thesis pecking order

Comparing Radical and Incremental Innovation in Venture Capital Syndication: Exploring the Influence of R&D Intensity and Sector-Specific Effects

thesis pecking order

Methodological Regulations Regarding the Assessment of the Innovation Activity of the Economic System Taking into Consideration the Peculiarities of the Activity of the Innovation Process Entities

Aghion P, Bond S, Klemm A, Marinescu I (2004) Technology and financial structure: are innovative firms different? J Eur Econ Assoc 2:277–288. doi: 10.1162/154247604323067989

Article   Google Scholar  

Ang JS (1991) Small business uniqueness and the theory of financial management. J Entrep Finance 1:1–13

Google Scholar  

Cassar G, Holmes S (2003) Capital structure and financing of SMEs: Australian evidence. Account Finance 43:123–147

Hall G, Hutchinson P, Michaelas N (2000) Industry effects on the determinants of unquoted SMEs’ capital structure. Int J Econ Bus 7:297–312. doi: 10.1080/13571510050197203

Hogan T, Hutson E (2005) Capital structure in new technology-based firms: evidence from the Irish software sector. Glob Finance J 15:369–387. doi: 10.1016/j.gfj.2004.12.001

Kubiak J (2013) Zjawisko asymetrii informacji a struktura kapitału przedsiębiorstw w Polsce. Wydawnictwo Uniwersytetu Ekonomicznego w Poznaniu, Poznań

Lopez-Gracia J, Aybar-Arias C (2000) An empirical approach to the financial behaviour of small and medium sized companies. Small Bus Econ 14:55–63. doi: 10.1023/A:1008139518709

Myers SC (1984) The capital structure puzzle. J Finance 39:574–592

Myers SC, Majluf NS (1984) Corporate financing and investment decisions when firms have information that investors do not have. J Financ Econ 13:187–221

Paul Stuart, Whittam Geoff, Wyper Janette (2007) The pecking order hypothesis: does it apply to start-up firms? J Small Bus Enterp Dev 14:8–21. doi: 10.1108/14626000710727854

Schäfer D, Werwatz A, Zimmermann V (2004) The determinants of debt and (private) equity financing: the case of young, innovative SMEs from Germany. Ind Innov 11:225–248. doi: 10.1080/1366271042000265393

Van Caneghem T, Van Campenhout G (2012) Quantity and quality of information and SME financial structure. Small Bus Econ 39:341–358

Zoppa A, McMahon RG (2002) Pecking order theory and the financial structure of manufacturing SMEs from Australia’s business longitudinal survey. Small Enterp Res 10:23–42

Download references

Acknowledgments

The project was funded by the National Science Centre allocated on the basis of the decision number DEC-2013/11/D/HS4/03941.

Author information

Authors and affiliations.

Department of Corporate Finance Management, Wrocław University of Economics, ul. Komandorska 118-120, 53-345, Wrocław, Poland

Katarzyna Prędkiewicz

Department of Finance, Wrocław University of Economics, ul. Komandorska 118-120, 53-345, Wrocław, Poland

Paweł Prędkiewicz

You can also search for this author in PubMed   Google Scholar

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Katarzyna Prędkiewicz .

Editor information

Editors and affiliations.

Faculty of Finance and Accounting, University of Economics, Prague, Czech Republic

David Procházka

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2017 Springer International Publishing AG

About this paper

Cite this paper.

Prędkiewicz, K., Prędkiewicz, P. (2017). Pecking Order Theory and Innovativeness of Companies. In: Procházka, D. (eds) New Trends in Finance and Accounting . Springer Proceedings in Business and Economics. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-49559-0_58

Download citation

DOI : https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-49559-0_58

Published : 28 December 2016

Publisher Name : Springer, Cham

Print ISBN : 978-3-319-49558-3

Online ISBN : 978-3-319-49559-0

eBook Packages : Business and Management Business and Management (R0)

Share this paper

Anyone you share the following link with will be able to read this content:

Sorry, a shareable link is not currently available for this article.

Provided by the Springer Nature SharedIt content-sharing initiative

  • Publish with us

Policies and ethics

  • Find a journal
  • Track your research

To read this content please select one of the options below:

Please note you do not have access to teaching notes, smes capital structure: trade-off or pecking order theory: a systematic review.

Journal of Small Business and Enterprise Development

ISSN : 1462-6004

Article publication date: 12 June 2018

Issue publication date: 28 January 2019

The purpose of this paper is to organize and present the literature related to firm’s capital structure across the years and find the most relevant publications and authors in the research area. Moreover, the authors pretend to fill the gap in the literature by studying different works and their compatibility with the main theories.

Design/methodology/approach

The systematic literature review is conducted by using the Scopus database. The methodology applied is through a concise searching considering keywords, the most cited papers, the latest publications and theories that explain small and medium enterprises (SMEs) capital structure.

Some key aspects about the capital structure of firms and SMEs are identified, such as documents per year, type of publications, the most used languages, the top journals, the most cited papers, the most productive and influential authors and the latest published papers.

Research limitations/implications

The information presented is only informative from the Scopus database. Hence, this work only gives a general orientation of the most relevant research and its tendency of this database. More exhaustive works could be done using different keywords and analyzing other firms’ characteristics.

Practical implications

This kind of study is effective in evaluating the scientific production and to find the most important contributions of the subject. Furthermore, this information is useful for researchers’ studies on SME capital structure to underline the research direction and to be acquainted with the literature tendency.

Originality/value

There are not similar works that delve into the literature respect to SME capital structure and compare the main theories in relation to empirical works. Therefore, a synthesized evolution of previous works related to the capital structure of firms and SMEs is presented.

  • Capital structure
  • Systematic literature review
  • Pecking order theory
  • Trade-off theory

Martinez, L.B. , Scherger, V. and Guercio, M.B. (2019), "SMEs capital structure: trade-off or pecking order theory: a systematic review", Journal of Small Business and Enterprise Development , Vol. 26 No. 1, pp. 105-132. https://doi.org/10.1108/JSBED-12-2017-0387

Emerald Publishing Limited

Copyright © 2018, Emerald Publishing Limited

Related articles

All feedback is valuable.

Please share your general feedback

Report an issue or find answers to frequently asked questions

Contact Customer Support

Pecking Order Theory for Government Finance

30 Pages Posted: 27 Mar 2019

Anton Miglo

Toronto School of Finance

Date Written: 2018

In this article we argue that asymmetric information can explain why seignorage is an inferior choice to debt for governments. We also argue that the Ricardian equivalence for governments is very similar to what the Modigliani-Miller proposition is for corporations. Our model is based on Bolton and Huang (2018) in that money for governments is similar to what equity is for corporations. In contrast to their model, our model considers rational economic agents.

Keywords: government finance, pecking order, capital structure, money, Ricardian Equivalence, Modigliani-Miller Proposition, asymmetric information

JEL Classification: D25, D82, D86, E40, E51, E52, E63, G32

Suggested Citation: Suggested Citation

Anton Miglo (Contact Author)

Toronto school of finance ( email ).

Toronto, Ontario M5S2W8 Canada

HOME PAGE: http://https://torontoschooloffinance.ca/anton-miglo/

Do you have a job opening that you would like to promote on SSRN?

Paper statistics, related ejournals, corporate finance: capital structure & payout policies ejournal.

Subscribe to this fee journal for more curated articles on this topic

European Finance eJournal

European economics: macroeconomics & monetary economics ejournal, political institutions: parties, interest groups & other political organizations ejournal, political economy - development: fiscal & monetary policy ejournal.

Pecking Order Theory

"Managers follow a hierarchy when considering sources of financing"

What is the Pecking Order Theory?

The Pecking Order Theory, also known as the Pecking Order Model, relates to a company’s capital structure . Made popular by Stewart Myers and Nicolas Majluf in 1984, the theory states that managers follow a hierarchy when considering sources of financing.

Pecking Order Theory

The pecking order theory states that managers display the following preference of sources to fund investment opportunities: first, through the company’s retained earnings, followed by debt, and choosing equity financing as a last resort.

Illustration of the Pecking Order Theory

The following diagram illustrates the pecking order theory:

Pecking Order Theory

Understanding the Pecking Order Theory

The pecking order theory arises from the concept of asymmetric information . Asymmetric information, also known as information failure, occurs when one party possesses more (better) information than another party, which causes an imbalance in transaction power.

Company managers typically possess more information regarding the company’s performance, prospects, risks, and future outlook than external users such as creditors (debt holders) and investors ( shareholders ). Therefore, to compensate for information asymmetry, external users demand a higher return to counter the risk that they are taking. In essence, due to information asymmetry, external sources of finances demand a higher rate of return to compensate for higher risk.

In the context of the pecking order theory, retained earnings financing (internal financing) comes directly from the company and minimizes information asymmetry. As opposed to external financing, such as debt or equity financing where the company must incur fees to obtain external financing, internal financing is the cheapest and most convenient source of financing.

When a company finances an investment opportunity through external financing (debt or equity), a higher return is demanded because creditors and investors possess less information regarding the company, as opposed to managers. In terms of external financing, managers prefer to use debt over equity – the cost of debt is lower compared to the cost of equity.

The issuance of debt often signals an undervalued stock and confidence that the board believes the investment is profitable. On the other hand, the issuance of equity sends a negative signal that the stock is overvalued and that the management is looking to generate financing by diluting shares in the company.

When thinking of the pecking order theory, it is useful to consider the seniority of claims to assets. Debtholders require a lower return as opposed to stockholders because they are entitled to a higher claim to assets (in the event of a bankruptcy). Therefore, when considering sources of financing, the cheapest is through retained earnings, second through debt, and third through equity.

Example of the Pecking Order Theory

Suppose ABC Company is looking to raise $10 million for an investment project. The company’s stock price is currently trading at $53.77. Three options are available for ABC Company:

  • Finance the project directly through retained earnings;
  • One-year debt financing with an interest rate of 9%, although management believes that 7% is the fair rate
  • Issuance of equity that will underprice the current stock price by 7%.

What would be the cost to shareholders for each of the three options?

Option 1 : If management finances the project directly through retained earnings, the cost is $10 million .

Option 2 : If management finances the project through debt issuance, the one-year debt would cost $10.8 million ($10 x 1.08 = $10.8). Discounting it back one year with the management’s fair rate would yield a cost of $10.09 million ($10.8 / 1.07 = $10.09 million).

Option 3 : If management finances the project through equity issuance, to raise $10 million, the company would need to sell 200,000 shares ($53.77 x 0.93 = $50, $10,000,000 / $50 = 200,000 shares). The true value of the shares would be $10.75 million ($53.77 x 200,000 shares = $10.75 million). Therefore, the cost would be $10.75 million .

As illustrated, management should first finance the project through retained earnings, second through debt, and lastly through equity.

Key Takeaways of the Pecking Order Theory

The pecking order theory relates to a company’s capital structure in that it helps explain why companies prefer to finance investment projects with internal financing first, debt second, and equity last. The pecking order theory arises from information asymmetry and explains that equity financing is the costliest and should be used as a last resort to obtain financing.

Additional Resources

Thank you for reading CFI’s guide to Pecking Order Theory. To keep advancing your career, the additional CFI resources below will be useful:

  • Cost of Capital
  • Debt vs Equity Financing
  • Project Finance
  • Revenue-based Financing
  • See all valuation resources
  • Share this article

Excel Fundamentals - Formulas for Finance

Create a free account to unlock this Template

Access and download collection of free Templates to help power your productivity and performance.

Already have an account? Log in

Supercharge your skills with Premium Templates

Take your learning and productivity to the next level with our Premium Templates.

Upgrading to a paid membership gives you access to our extensive collection of plug-and-play Templates designed to power your performance—as well as CFI's full course catalog and accredited Certification Programs.

Already have a Self-Study or Full-Immersion membership? Log in

Access Exclusive Templates

Gain unlimited access to more than 250 productivity Templates, CFI's full course catalog and accredited Certification Programs, hundreds of resources, expert reviews and support, the chance to work with real-world finance and research tools, and more.

Already have a Full-Immersion membership? Log in

  • Open access
  • Published: 26 November 2020

Testing the pecking order theory of capital structure: the case of Islamic financing modes

  • Moncef Guizani 1  

Future Business Journal volume  6 , Article number:  38 ( 2020 ) Cite this article

9326 Accesses

3 Citations

Metrics details

The purpose of this paper is to examine whether or not the basic premises according to the pecking order theory provide an explanation for the capital structure mix of firms operating under Islamic principles. Pooled OLS and random effect regressions were performed to test the pecking order theory applying data from a sample of 66 Islamic firms listed on Kingdom of Saudi Arabia stock market over the period 2006–2016. The results show that sale-based instruments ( Murabahah , Ijara ) track the financial deficit quite closely followed by equity financing and as the last alternative to finance deficit, Islamic firms issue Sukuk . In the crisis period, these firms seem more reliant on equity, then on sale-based instrument and on Sukuk as last option. The study findings also indicate that the cumulative financing deficit does not wipe out the effects of conventional variables, although it is empirically significant. This provides no support for the pecking order theory attempted by Saudi Islamic firms. This research highlights the capital structure choice of firms operating under Islamic principles. It explores the implication of the relevant Islamic principles on corporate financing preferences. It can serve firm executive managers in their financing decisions to add value to the companies.

Introduction

Making financing decisions for firms is one of the most fundamental topics in contemporary finance research since the influential studies of Modigliani and Miller [ 26 ] on capital structure irrelevancy. Once we move away from a model of perfect capital markets, most theories have sought to explain how companies choose a particular combination of debt and equity by introducing frictions omitted in the original Modigliani and Miller framework. The pecking order theory (POT) is among the most influential theories of capital structure.

Pioneered by Myers [ 28 ] and Myers and Majluf [ 29 ], pecking order refers to managers’ preferences for funding sources to cover their financing needs. The theory states that managers prefer internal to external financing, and, when outside funds are necessary, they prefer debt to equity because of lower information costs associated with debt issues. They issue equity as the last alternative. Managers follow this financing hierarchy behavior to avoid both the wealth transfer to outsiders and the negative effect of adverse selection inherent to external funding sources.

In the last two decades, the business community had witnessed a drastic growth of Islamic funds all over the world. Islamic finance has attracted a fair amount of attention from stock market participants. The financial market around the world experienced exceptional growth in Islamic finance [ 30 ]. In addition, the recent global financial crisis has added further to the attraction of Islamic finance to practitioners, monetary authorities and academic scholars in their search for a viable and resilient alternative financial system [ 17 ]. This increasing market share of Islamic banking begs the question of the importance of Islamic financing instruments in firms’ financing choice.

Islamic firms consider Islamic business principles crucial to their business operations. They would not engage in any activity which is forbidden by Islam. For example, no firm in an Islamic society would be operating in the production or sale of alcoholic drinks or the production or sale of pigs, or gambling or forbidden speculation, or in lending or borrowing money at fixed interest rates. By reviewing the main restrictions, one can understand how these restrictions might alter Islamic firms’ capital structure decisions.

Limited research has been conducted in the areas of financing hierarchy of Islamic financial instruments. Kayed [ 19 ] argues that the dominant modes of finance that are being practiced by the majority of Islamic financial institutions are risk-free financing schemes such as Murabahah and Ijara . In a similar vein, Ismal [ 18 ] finds that Murabahah financing in the Indonesian Islamic banking industry is the most favored form of Islamic financing. Such a contract dominates 56.24% the total Islamic financing, followed by Mudarabah financing (18.54%) and Musharakah financing (9.76%). Sakti et al. [ 33 ] suggest that the presence of less asymmetric information and lower agency costs between shareholders and managers lead Islamic banks to opt for equity financing. However, lower bankruptcy costs and lower agency costs between shareholders and debt holders lead Islamic banks to favor debt-based financing. Miah and Suzuki [ 24 ] show that about 90% of the total financing in GCC countries are concentrated on Murabahah , which is the result of existing institutional underpinnings. GCC Islamic banks are involved with PLS-based financing only limitedly.

Thus, in light of the above, it is worth exploring the implications of the relevant Islamic principles on the Islamic firms’ capital structure choice. In particular, this study sheds light on whether the basic premises according to the POT provide an explanation for the capital structure mix of KSA Islamic firms.

KSA is an interesting case for studying the financing hierarchy of Islamic financial instruments. Most Saudi listed firms, with their compliance to Sharia rules, are thus differentiated from their conventional counterparts. The legal system of KSA is based on Islamic law (Sharia) derived from the Qur’an and the Sunnah (the traditions of the Islamic prophet Muhammad), which prohibits loan interests whether giving or taking.

This study contributes to existing literature in two ways. First, it highlights the capital structure choice of firms operating under Islamic principles. It explores the implication of the relevant Islamic principles on the financing preferences of KSA firms. Due to the prohibition of interest on debt and promotion of profit and loss sharing, Islamic financing invokes a question on whether the corporate capital structure choice will be influenced by a set of factors similar to conventional finance. Second, the present paper provides further evidence on the impact of financial crisis on the firms’ capital structure choice in a period of considerable slowdown in the world. The credit shortages that characterize the last financial crisis have resulted in changing of firms’ demand for credit. This has raised the role of Islamic-based financing as a substitution for the conventional finance system [ 35 ]. Therefore, given the high penetration of Islamic finance against conventional finance in KSA, this study provides insights into how the contraction of bank lending during the 2008–2009 crisis affects the corporate capital structure choice in an Islamic finance setting.

Following this introductory section, the rest of the study is organized as follows: “ Literature review ” section discusses the costs of financial instruments and reviews existing studies in the literature. “ Data and methodology ” section discusses the data and the theoretical framework. “ Results and discussion ” section presents the empirical findings, while “ Conclusion ” section concludes with policy implications.

Literature review

Cost structure of islamic financial instruments.

Islamic financial instruments are based on the principles that they exclude interest (riba), not possess major uncertainty (gharar) and not have gambling like features (Maysir). Under these principles, Islamic modes of financing can be broadly classified into sale-based, profit-loss sharing (PLS) and hybrid instruments. Sale-based instruments are fixed-income instruments that replicate the payoff of a debt instrument by applying the sum paid in advance plus a predefined mark-up. They include: Murabahah , Salam , Istisna and Ijara . PLS instruments are Islamic participation contracts based on the principle of profit and loss sharing. They include: Mudarabah and Musharakah . Hybrid instruments have the characteristics of both, sale-based and PLS instruments. They include Sukuk. Footnote 1

Islamic financial contracts may generally involve direct and indirect costs. To quantify different costs, we follow Ahmed [ 1 ] by ranking them as high, medium, low and negligible. The following table summarizes the cost structure of different financial instruments (Table  1 ).

Murabahah and Ijara are considered as debt-based instruments having low risk relative to equity-based instruments. Accordingly, they have the lower cost of funds. Given that they are negotiated with financial institutions, their contracting costs are relatively low and they imply no floatation costs as in case of securities [ 1 ]. As financing techniques, Murabahah and Ijara involve no ownership dilution, and thus, their dilution costs are negligible. In addition, since the bank holds the ownership of the asset, these contracts would reduce the problems of asymmetric information associated with financing to more opaque borrowers. Under contracts such as Murabahah and Ijara , the rate of return is fixed and predetermined and adverse selection and moral hazard problems would not arise. In contrast, as they are debt-based instruments, they have inherent distress costs.

With respect to equity-based instruments, they are based on the principle of profit and loss sharing. Their costs of funds are relatively high. However, given that Mudarabah contracts are not affected by dividend policy, their cost of funds will be smaller than the Musharakah contracts. Moreover, their floatation costs will be relatively lower than those for Musharakah contracts. On the other hand, a firm will choose Mudarabah instead of Musharakah contract to avoid ownership dilution. Mudarabah is a PLS contract where the ownership of the capital or invested assets remain with the fund provider at all times and the entrepreneur provides effort and management expertise. In contrast, the Musharakah contract involves a partnership where both partners, that is, entrepreneur and investor jointly provide the capital and manage the venture. In addition, PLS contracts are inherently vulnerable to asymmetric information problems. These problems are relatively higher in the case of Mudarabah contract. Asymmetric information on Mudarabah contract arises because the entrepreneur who manages the Mudarabah fund has full control of the project and has more information regarding the project, which the capital provider does not usually have access to. Consequently, two major problems are issued from the inefficiency in information delegation: adverse selection and moral hazard problems.

As for Sukuks , they are considered as hybrid securities, bearing the features of stocks and bonds. Similar to a bond, Sukuk has a maturity date and some of these securities are usually of fixed revenue and a final payment at the maturity date [ 37 ]. Sukuk holders have recourse to the assets in the event of default, or if the issuers have difficulty in repaying. This involves that they have low cost of funds. In addition, given their tradability in secondary market, Sukuks are liquid instruments, which involve a medium low floatation costs. On the other hand, although the Sukuks are indicative of some sort of partnership and ownership of the holder in respect of the asset, they lack right of voting and interfering in underlying asset. These Islamic instruments involve a high information cost. Due to their specific structuring, Sukuks are especially exposed to moral hazard and adverse selection problems [ 21 ].

The empirical findings of the POT: conventional versus Islamic-compliant firms

There has been an intense debate over the capital structure choice for conventional firms, particularly in the recent literature. In spite of an enormous volume of research, the hierarchy or pecking order among different sources of funds remains equivocal. One branch of research has provided evidence that is consistent with managers’ pecking order preference. Shyam-Sunder and Myers [ 34 ] find that the pecking order model is an excellent first-order descriptor of financing behavior in US firms. Booth et al. [ 6 ] find result in favor of the POT in developing countries. In the same vein, Lemmon et al. [ 23 ] find evidence in tune with the POT. After controlling for debt capacity, the authors show that firms’ financing behavior follows the financing hierarchy described by the pecking order model.

However, other empirical studies have found no support of the POT predictions. For instance, Frank and Goyal [ 14 ] find results that are surprising from the perspective of the POT. Using a sample of US firms, the authors show that debt financing does not dominate equity financing in magnitude. The evidence provided by Fama and French [ 13 ] strongly rejects the POT hypothesis. They reveal that firms heavily rely on equity financing to fill up deficiency needs. Komera and Lukose [ 22 ] argue that the POT fails to explain Indian firms’ financing choices. Their estimated annual pecking order coefficients show no support for the financing choices described by the POT. Allini et al. [ 2 ] support the predictions of a modified POT in Egypt. They identify that internally generated funds are the preferred option for Egyptian firms followed by equity, where a financial deficit is present, and finally debt finance as a last resort.

In spite of Sharia restrictions on interest, little is known about how these restrictions translate into capital structure decisions in Islamic countries. Using sample of firms in Islamic and non-Islamic countries, Gunn and Shackman [ 15 ] provide evidence that Islamic law does not disadvantage firms in terms of the overall levels of debt compared to equity financing. The findings reveal no difference in the level of total debt to total assets when comparing capital structure in firms from Islamic countries to firms in non-Islamic countries. Minhat and Dzolkarnaini [ 25 ] addressed the question of which firms use Islamic financing. They provide evidence that Islamic financing attracts less profitable firms due to the presence of adverse selection among Islamic financiers. Yildirim et al. [ 36 ] compared the key capital structure determinants between Sharia-compliant (SC) and non-Sharia-Compliant (NSC) firms. Due to the restrictions imposed by Sharia rules, it is expected that SC firms exhibit different capital structure compared to their NSC peers. Their results show that most of the determinants do exhibit different effects among both firm types. The authors document that capital structure decisions for SC and NSC firms are better explained by the pecking order for book leverage and by the trade-off theory for market leverage. In the same token, Alnoria and Alqahtani [ 3 ] investigate the effect of Sharia-compliance status on firms’ capital structure decisions in non-financial firms in the KSA market. They find that SC firms have significantly lower levels of leverage and slower speeds of adjustment than NSC firms. The authors explain these findings by the financing restrictions to which SC firms are subject, creating a finance supply gap for these firms and higher adjustment costs.

Data and methodology

Data sources and sample.

The study sample consists of non-financial companies that are publicly traded on the KSA stock exchange. The analysis is about the period from 2006 to 2016. The financial and market data used in this research were hand-collected from listed firms’ annual reports provided by the website https://www.argaam.com . We exclude financial firms (banks and insurance) due to their specific regulations. We also exclude firms with missing information over the study period.

This study follows the Sharia Guidelines of Alrajhi bank for Trading and Investment in Stocks. The Sharia Board of Alrajhi Bank has issued its resolution No. (485) regarding the legal rule on the investment and trading in the stocks of the joint stock companies, as follows:

Joint stock companies, in terms of their objectives, activities and controls of dealing in their stocks, are classified into three types:

Joint stock companies with permissible objectives and activities;

Joint stock companies with illicit objectives and activities (e.g., tobacco, pork, gambling, interest-bearing banking activities);

Companies whose objectives and activities are permissible but may have illicit matters in their dealings, such as dealing in usurious interest-bearing loans or deposits.

According to this classification, we define Islamic firms as those of type one. These firms use non-interest based financing modes to finance their assets.

Table  2 describes the sample selection procedure. The final sample consists of 66 firms with a total of 726 firm-year observations.

Theoretical framework and measures of variables

This study employs the methodology of Shyam-Sunder and Myers [ 34 ] and Frank and Goyal [ 14 ] to test the POT. The test advanced by the authors is based on the implication that, under the POT, a substantial amount of inter-temporal variation in net debt issue (ΔD) should be explained by a single variable, the funds flow deficit (DEF). The DEF variable is given by the following identity:

where DIV t : cash dividends in year t ; I t : net investment in year t ; Δ W t : change in working capital in year t ; C t : cash flows after interest and taxes in year t ; Δ D t : net debt issued in year t ; Δ E t : net equity issued in year t .

According to Shyam-Sunder and Myers [ 34 ], the testing strategy of the pecking order hypothesis relies on the following simple model:

where α po and β po are the pecking order parameters and e i , t is an error term. In Eq. ( 2 ), the strong form test of the pecking order model predicts that α po  = 0 and β po  = 1 [ 34 ]. However, according to Chirinko and Singha [ 9 ], the later form is very restrictive and therefore will not be very useful in evaluating the pecking order model. The authors propose a semi-strong form, which states that firms meet their deficit-in-funds by relying initially and primarily on debt finance.

Given the characteristics of Islamic financial instruments, we propose the following models:

where NDI is net debt issued ( Murabahah , Ijara ).

where NSKI is net Sukuk issued.

Because of the presence of debt capacity constraints, firms must resort to equity issues. Following Chirinko and Singha [ 9 ] argument, the present study uses Eq. ( 5 ) below to be compared with Eqs. ( 3 ) and ( 4 ).

where NQI is net equity issued.

Moreover, to test the predictions of the POT in KSA context, the present paper refers to the modified conventional regression of leverage of Frank and Goyal [ 14 ]. In the following regression equation, the cumulative financing deficit (CDEF) replaces the financing deficit (DEF) because of using levels of leverage rather than changes in leverage [ 8 ].

where LEV refers to book leverage (long-term debt/total assets) or market-based debt (long-term debt to market capitalization), TAN is the tangibility of assets (fixed assets/total assets), MTB is the market-to-book ratio (the ratio of the sum of the market value of equity and the book value of debt to the book value of assets), LS is the size of the firm (log of assets), PRF is the profitability (operating income/total assets), and CDEF is the cumulative financing deficit (the ratio of cumulative financing deficit to the book value of assets). ( μ i ) is the unobservable individual heterogeneity, and (υ i,t ) is the remainder disturbance or the usual disturbance in the regression model that varies with individual units and time. According to Frank and Goyal [ 14 ], the pecking order predicts that β TAN  < 0, β MTB  < 0, β LS  > 0, β PRF  < 0, and β CDEF  > 0.

Equation ( 6 ) is simply a modified conventional regression with cumulative financing deficit as an added factor. If the inclusion of the cumulative financial deficit variable should wipe out the effect of the other variables, then the predictions of the POT would be supported. Otherwise, the predictions of the POT would be contradicted [ 2 , 14 ].

Results and discussion

Descriptive statistics.

Table  3 provides the main summary statistics for the variables used in the empirical analysis. Interestingly, to track their financing deficit, KSA firms first issue debt-based instruments ( Murabahah , Ijara ), then equity, and finally they issue Sukuk as a last resort. On average, the net debt issued is 1.4% of total assets higher than 0.9% of net equity issued and 0.2% of net Sukuk . This suggests the preference of KSA firms to issue debt-based instruments rather than equity and Sukuk .

The average values of book-based debt and market-based debt are 27.1% and 25.7%, respectively. Looking at these results in comparison with those in other developing and developed countries, Allini et al. [ 2 ] find that the book-based debt and market-based debt means in Egypt are 17%, and 14%, respectively. Chen et al. [ 8 ] find them to be 39% and 35% in Taiwan. In European context, Moradi and Paulet [ 27 ] find a book-based debt mean of 26% in Austria, 23% in Belgium, 20% in France, 21% in Germany, 20% in Luxembourg and 26% in Netherlands.

With regard to other variables, the results show a mean value of market-to-book ratio of 1.928, with a range from 0.731 to 6.675. The tangible assets as a percentage of total assets average 57.7%. The average firms’ size measured by the log of total assets is about 9.333. The KSA firms’ profitability averages 9.1% and ranges between − 50.9% and 110.3%.

Tests of pecking order of Islamic financial instruments

Consistent with previous works [ 9 , 34 ], this study seeks to examine how well Islamic financial instruments track the financing deficit.

The selection of the appropriate model was made following four different tests developed by Baltagi [ 5 ], Chow [ 10 ], Hausman [ 16 ], and Breusch and Pagan [ 7 ]. The F test [ 5 ] determines the best model between pooled OLS and the alternatives of panel data (i.e., fixed and random effects, respectively). A Chow test was performed to distinguish between the pooled OLS model and the fixed effect model. The Breusch and Pagan Lagrangian multiplier (LM test) was performed to examine the existence of random effects. The Hausman test is used to select the best model between the random effects model and the alternative fixed effects model.

The results of the F test, Chow test and Breusch and Pagan test (Tables  4 and 5 ) reveal that the pooled OLS estimators are the most appropriate. The statistics of these tests are not significant.

Table  4 summarizes the basic ordinary least squares (OLS) tests. The dependent variables are net debt ( Murabahah , Ijara ) issued, net Sukuk issued, total debt issued and net equity issued, all scaled by book assets. The results show that the constant, α , is close to zero in all regressions. The slope parameter, β , ranges from 0.071 to 0.614 depending on the dependent variable. Interestingly, it seems that sale-based instruments ( Murabahah , Ijara ) track the financial deficit much closer as they are cheaper than other alternatives and they do not dilute ownership. The estimated coefficient on financial deficit as 0.543 is still far below from observed coefficient for conventional firms in the US market, that ranging between 0.75 and 0.85 [ 34 ]. However, it is still far above from observed coefficients in Egyptian market and Taiwan market that are 0.340 and 0.309, respectively [ 2 , 8 ].

If the firm needs more funds but cannot use debt-based instruments due to the debt-ratio constraint, Footnote 2 then it moves to equity financing. Regarding net equity issued, the results show a positive and significant coefficient (0.359) associated with financial deficit. Looking at these results in comparison with those in other developing countries, Allini et al. [ 2 ] find a coefficient of 0.519 in Egypt, and Chen et al. [ 8 ] find it to be 0.675 in Taiwan.

As a last alternative to finance deficit, Islamic firms issue Sukuk . The results reveal a positive low coefficient (0.071) of financial deficit on net Sukuk issued. This can be explained by the under-development of Sukuk market in KSA. According to Alshamrani [ 4 ], the Sukuk market in KSA is new and immature; the first issuance of Sukuk was in 2004. The author emphasizes that the issuance of Sukuk in Saudi Arabia is suffering from heavy regulation and supervision drawbacks, which need to be identified in order to resolve the problems of regulation and insufficiency of supervision. This argument aligns with Alnoria and Alqahtani [ 3 ], who state that because of its complexity, firms are discouraged from issuing a Sukuk or at least making it their first option.

In sum, capital choice decision of Islamic-compliant firms seems to follow a modified POT, in which firms rely on retained profit, followed by sale-based instrument ( Murabahah , Ijara ), then equity, with Sukuk as the last option.

We also ran tests using deficits, debt issues, Sukuk issues and equity issues according to crisis periods. The results presented in Table  5 support the same modified POT in the pre and post-crisis only. Financial deficit is financed by sale-based instrument ( Murabahah , Ijara ), then equity, and lastly by Sukuk . However, the POT is highly violated in the crisis period. The results displayed in Table  5 show less reliance of firms on debt issuance in the crisis period. KSA firms seem more reliant on equity, then on sale-based instrument and on Sukuk as last alternative. Hence, KSA firms that are willing to expand often find it difficult to obtain financing from financial institutions in the crisis period and are thus credit constrained. This constitutes the “financing-gap” encountered by firms and this gap is more prevalent in crisis period. The financial crisis arguably provides a shock to the supply of external financing resulting in lending contraction for banking system. Consequently, firms will experience a fall in corporate borrowing and capital expenditures. This reflects in less leverage ratios in the crisis period. This argument aligns with Dewally and Shao [ 11 ] who suggest that the liquidity shocks to the short-term funding markets impose liquidity constraints to banks, resulting in lending cut and changes in the capital structure of corporations.

Tests of conventional leverage regressions

The next test of the theory is to see how the financing deficit works when added to a conventional leverage regression. If the pecking order hypothesis is true, the inclusion of the financing deficit variable would increase the R 2 considerably (relative to running the regression without this variable) because the financing deficit should be the most important variable in the equation. In addition, we would expect that adding the financing deficit variable should render the effects of the other conventional explanatory variables insignificant.

First, we carry out two tests to check the existence of multicollinearity among the explanatory variables: the pairwise correlation matrix among the explanatory variables and the variance inflation factor (VIF). According to Kennedy [ 20 ], a multicollinearity problem arises if the correlation among the independent variables is greater than or equal to 0.80. As shown in Table  6 , the Pearson correlation coefficients appear to be relatively low and there is no correlation between the variables that reach 0.8. The low magnitude of correlations among the explanatory variables indicates that multicollinearity is not a problem for the sample.

Furthermore, a VIF test was performed to examine the existence of multicollinearity. As highlighted in Table  6 , all VIF values of explanatory variables are less than 4, supporting the previous conclusion of the absence of multicollinearity problem in the data. According to O’Brien [ 31 ], a VIF value exceeding 4 warrants further investigations, while a VIF value exceeding 10 is a sign of serious multicollinearity requiring correction.

Second, this study carried out two root tests on all the variables in order to confirm that all variables are stationary. In particular, we employed the augmented Dickey and Fuller [ 12 ] test (ADF) and the Phillips and Perron [ 32 ] test (PP). The results reported in Table  7 indicate that all variables are stationary at the first difference. Therefore, our models using the first difference operator are appropriate for avoiding spurious estimates.

Third, the selection of the appropriate model was made following four different tests developed by Baltagi [ 5 ], Chow [ 10 ], Hausman [ 16 ], and Breusch and Pagan [ 7 ]. The results reported in Tables  8 and 9 reveal that the individual effect models (fixed effects and the random effects) are the most appropriate. The statistics of F test, Chow test and Breusch and Pagan test are significant in all regressions. Thus, the Hausman [ 16 ] specification test was conducted to decide between the fixed effect model and the random effect model. The results show that all values of Hausman test are insignificant implying that the random effects model is preferred to the fixed effects model.

Table  8 provides the results for the full sample using Book-based debt and Market-based debt as independent variables. The conventional regressions before the deficit variable addition are provided in columns (1) and (3). The estimated coefficients on tangibility, the market-to-book ratio, firm size and profitability have the usual signs. The results show that the tangibility is found to be significant and positively related to both leverage measures which is inconsistent with the POT prediction. As debt has to be asset-backed in firms operating under Islamic principles, leverage will increase with the increase in tangible assets.

The coefficient signs are negative on the market-to-book ratio for both leverage measures. Like conventional firms, debt instruments in Islamic-compliant firms have high distress costs (see Table  1 ). Consequently, a negative relationship between firms’ future opportunities and their leverage choice will be established because growth firms are predicted to lose more of their value when they become financially distressed [ 14 ].

The coefficients associated with the size variable are positive and significant on both leverage measures consistent with the findings of Frank and Goyal [ 14 ]. In term of information asymmetries, large firms are expected to convey more information than small firms. This facilitates their access to the credit market which enhances their debt capacity. The results reveal that profitability is negatively related to both leverage measures, which is consistent with the POT and in line with most empirical research (e.g., [ 3 , 14 ]).

In columns (2) and (4), both leverage regressions are estimated with financing deficit as an additional explanatory variable. The results show that the cumulative financing deficit added about 2% and 4% to the explanatory power of the Book-based debt and Market-based debt regressions, respectively. Further, the results indicate that the addition of the deficit variable to the regression does not result in an effect on the magnitudes and significance of the coefficients on the conventional variables. However, the financing deficit is empirically relevant. Thus, the cumulative financing deficit works well in both leverage regressions, although the POT is rejected. This reflects that the current capital structure of Islamic-compliant firms in KSA is strongly related to cumulative financing deficit.

This result aligns with previous studies including Chen et al. [ 8 ] who find that the introduction of the cumulative financial deficit in leverage specifications did not have much influence on the significance of other conventional variables’ coefficients although the financing deficit is empirically significant. Similarly, Allini et al. [ 2 ] show that the inclusion of the cumulative financial deficit in leverage regressions did not affect the significance of the other conventional variables. Moreover, there is no gain in terms of the explanatory power of the regressions.

The same tests are done considering crisis period classification. Table  9 provides empirical results. To save space, we only report the results using the Book-based debt regression. Except market-to book ratio, most variables show the similar sign and significance to the all-firms’ sample. The coefficient associated with MTB variable is not significant in crisis and post-crisis periods.

Further, the results indicate that the inclusion of the cumulative financing deficit did not influence the signs, magnitudes and significance of the coefficients of conventional factors. As seen in Table  9 , the coefficient of the cumulative financing deficit is significant in all regression except in crisis period. This aligns with the original results about the reject of the POT in KSA Islamic firms. In addition, the findings reflect the financial behavior disturbance of KSA firms during the crisis period.

The objective of this study was to investigate whether the POT is an accurate means to describe the incremental financing practices by firms operating under Islamic principles.

Employing panel data analysis, this study first examines how well Islamic financial instruments track the financing deficit. The results show that sale-based instruments ( Murabahah , Ijara ) track the financial deficit much closer as they are cheaper than other alternatives and they do not dilute ownership. If the firm needs more funds but cannot use debt-based instruments due to the debt-ratio constraint, then it moves to equity financing. As a last alternative to finance deficit, Islamic-compliant firms issue Sukuk . This can be explained by the under-development of Sukuk market in KSA. Further, the results reveal high violation of the POT in the crisis period. Islamic-compliant firms seem more reliant on equity, then on sale-based instrument and on Sukuk as last alternative. Due to credit constraints in the crisis period, debt financing is less preferred and more equity capital financing is used.

Next, the study findings indicate that the inclusion of the cumulative financing deficit does not wipe out the effects of conventional variables, although it is empirically significant. This provides no support for the POT attempts by KSA Islamic-compliant firms.

Overall, it seems that the issuance activity of Islamic-compliant firms is more closely to the need of funds instead of adhering to a hierarchy of financing sources.

There are several important areas where this study makes original contributions to the related literature. First, this research extends literature on capital structure. It highlights the capital structure choice of firms operating under Islamic principles. Second, this research focuses on the capital structure of Islamic-compliant firms in KSA, which has not been previously tackled by any research effort. Third, the present paper sheds light on the impact of the global financial crisis on Islamic banking, and therefore, on the Islamic firms’ capital structure choice. Finally, the findings will contribute significantly to the body of knowledge as well as to practitioners and to firms that would like to operate under Islamic principles.

Several implications can be derived from the study results. First, due to the lack of legislative and regulatory framework of Sukuk issuance, it is recommended to update the present regulations for the offering and issuance of securities in KSA in order to cover Sukuk . In this regard, policymakers, bankers and standard-setting organizations should undertake more collective work to simplify the process of issuing Islamic financial instruments, including Sukuk . Second, the Saudi government has to encourage the private sector to be more innovative in developing products and services that are in line with Sharia principles. Finally, to attract investors, the Saudi Capital Market Authority (CMA) has to encourage transaction, efficiency and liquidity of Islamic financial instruments.

The paper identifies some areas where further research on topics related to capital structure of Islamic-compliant firms is needed. The failure of the POT to explain KSA firms’ financing choices strongly pushed researchers to test the market timing theory for the Saudi stock market. Further, scholars could re-examine the trade-off theory in the absence of interest tax shield as in an Islamic economy.

Availability of data and materials

The datasets generated and/or analyzed during the current study are available in the Argaam web site repository, www.argaam.com .

The AAOIFI Sharia Standard (17) defines Sukuk as being: “Certificates of equal value representing undivided shares in the ownership of tangible assets, usufructs and services or (in the ownership of) the assets of particular projects or special investment activities.”

The debt-ratio constraint maintains that it cannot exceed the ratio of tangible assets to total assets [ 1 ].

Abbreviations

Accounting and Auditing Organization for Islamic Financial Institutions

Capital Market Authority

Gulf Cooperation Council

Kingdom of Saudi Arabia

Non-Sharia-Compliant

Ordinary least squares

Profit and loss sharing

  • Pecking order theory

Saudi Monetary Authority

Sharia-compliant

Variance inflation factor

Ahmed H (2007) Issues in Islamic corporate finance: capital structure in firms. IRTI research paper series no. 70, Jeddah, Saudi Arabia

Allini A, Rakha S, McMillan DG, Caldarelli A (2018) Pecking order and market timing theory in emerging markets: the case of Egyptian firms. Res Int Bus Finance 44:297–308

Article   Google Scholar  

Alnoria F, Alqahtani F (2019) Capital structure and speed of adjustment in non-financial firms: does sharia compliance matter? Evidence from Saudi Arabia. Emerg Mark Rev 39:50–67

Alshamrani A (2014) Sukuk issuance and its regulatory framework in Saudi Arabia. J Islam Bank Finance 2(1):305–333

Google Scholar  

Baltagi BH (1995) Econometric analysis of panel data. Wiley, New York

Booth L, Aivazian V, Demirguc-Kunt A, Maksimovic V (2001) Capital structures in developing countries. J Finance 56(1):87–130

Breusch S, Pagan R (1980) The Lagrange multiplier test and its applications to model specification in econometrics. Rev Econ Stud 47(1):239–253

Chen DH, Chen CD, Chen J, Huang YF (2013) Panel data analyses of the pecking order theory and the market timing theory of capital structure in Taiwan. Int Rev Econ Finance 27:1–13

Chirinko RS, Singha AR (2000) Testing static tradeoff against pecking order models of capital structure: a critical comment. J Financ Econ 58(3):417–425

Chow GC (1960) Tests of equality between sets of coefficients in two linear regressions. Econometrica 28:591

Dewally M, Shao Y (2014) Liquidity crisis, relationship lending and corporate finance. J Bank Finance 39:223–239

Dickey DA, Fuller WA (1981) Likelihood ratio statistics for autoregressive time series with a unit root. Econometrica 49:1057

Fama EF, French KR (2005) Financing decisions: who issues stock? J Financ Econ 76(3):549–582

Frank MZ, Goyal VK (2003) Testing the pecking order theory of capital structure. J Financ Econ 67(2):217–248

Gunn T, Shackman J (2014) A comparative analysis of the implications of the Islamic religion on corporate capital structures of firms in emerging market countries. Int J Islam Middle East Finance Manag 7(3):277–287

Hausman J (1978) Specification tests in econometrics. Econometrica 46:1251–1271

Ibrahim MH (2015) Issues in Islamic banking and finance: Islamic banks, Shari’ah-compliant investment and sukuk. Pac Basin Finance J 34(4):185–191

Ismal R (2014) Assessing the gold Murabahah in Islamic banking. Int J Commer Manag 24(4):367–382

Kayed RN (2012) The entrepreneurial role of profit-and-loss sharing modes of finance: theory and practice. Int J Islam Middle East Finance Manag 5(3):203–228

Kennedy P (1985) A guide to econometrics. Massachusetts Institute of Technology Press, Cambridge

Klein PO, Weill L (2016) Why do companies issue Sukuk? Rev Financ Econ 31:26–33

Komera S, Lukose J (2015) Capital structure choice, information asymmetry, and debt capacity: evidence from India. J Econ Finance 39(4):807–823

Lemmon ML, Roberts MR, Zender JF (2008) Back to the beginning: persistence and the cross-section of corporate capital structure. J Finance 63(4):1575–1608

Miah MD, Suzuki Y (2020) Murabaha syndrome of Islamic banks: a paradox or product of the system? J Islam Account Bus Res 11(7):1363–1378

Minhat M, Dzolkarnaini N (2016) Which firms use Islamic financing? Econ Lett 150:15–17

Modigliani F, Miller M (1958) The cost of capital corporation finance, and the theory of investment. Am Econ Rev 48(3):261–297

Moradi A, Paulet E (2019) The firm-specific determinants of capital structure – An empirical analysis of firms before and during the Euro Crisis. Res Int Bus Finance 47(1):150–161

Myers SC (1984) The capital structure puzzle. J Finance 39(3):575–592

Myers SC, Majluf NS (1984) Corporate financing and investment decisions when firms have information that investors do not have. J Financ Econ 13(2):187–221

Naz I, Shah SMA, Kutan AM (2017) Do managers of sharia: compliant firms have distinctive financial styles? J Int Financ Mark Inst Money 46:174–187

O’Brien RM (2007) A caution regarding rules of thumb for variance inflation factors. Qual Quant 41(5):673–690

Phillips PC, Perron P (1988) Testing for a unit root in time series regression. Biometrika 75:335

Sakti MR, Saiti B, Akhtar T (2017) Capital structure of Islamic banks: a critical review of theoretical and empirical research. Qual Res Financ Mark 9(3):292–308

Shyam-Sunder L, Myers S (1999) Testing static trade-off against pecking order models of capital structure. J Financ Econ 51(2):219–244

Smolo E, Mirakhor A (2010) The global financial crisis and its implications for the Islamic financial industry. Int J Islam Middle East Finance Manag 3(4):372–385

Yildirim R, Masih M, Bacha OI (2018) Determinants of capital structure: evidence from Shari’ah compliant and non-compliant firms. Pac Basin Finance J 51:198–219

Zolfaghari P (2017) An Introduction to Islamic Securities (Sukuk). Uppsala faculty of law working paper 2017:2

Download references

Acknowledgements

Not applicable.

There is no source of funding.

Author information

Authors and affiliations.

College of Science and Humanity Studies in Sulayel, Prince Sattam Bin Abdulaziz University – Kingdom of Saudi Arabia, Al-Kharj, Saudi Arabia

Moncef Guizani

You can also search for this author in PubMed   Google Scholar

Contributions

MG reviewed the literature, analyzed, interpreted and discussed the results. He is the only contributor in writing the manuscript. The author read and approved the final manuscript.

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Moncef Guizani .

Ethics declarations

Competing interests.

The authors declare that they have no competing interests.

Additional information

Publisher's note.

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Rights and permissions

Open Access This article is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License, which permits use, sharing, adaptation, distribution and reproduction in any medium or format, as long as you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons licence, and indicate if changes were made. The images or other third party material in this article are included in the article's Creative Commons licence, unless indicated otherwise in a credit line to the material. If material is not included in the article's Creative Commons licence and your intended use is not permitted by statutory regulation or exceeds the permitted use, you will need to obtain permission directly from the copyright holder. To view a copy of this licence, visit http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/ .

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article.

Guizani, M. Testing the pecking order theory of capital structure: the case of Islamic financing modes. Futur Bus J 6 , 38 (2020). https://doi.org/10.1186/s43093-020-00042-9

Download citation

Received : 28 November 2019

Accepted : 02 November 2020

Published : 26 November 2020

DOI : https://doi.org/10.1186/s43093-020-00042-9

Share this article

Anyone you share the following link with will be able to read this content:

Sorry, a shareable link is not currently available for this article.

Provided by the Springer Nature SharedIt content-sharing initiative

  • Capital structure
  • Islamic-compliant firms

thesis pecking order

IMAGES

  1. What Is Pecking Order Theory? (+Why It Exists and How to Use It)

    thesis pecking order

  2. Illustration of Pecking Order Theory Source: Corporate Finance

    thesis pecking order

  3. Pecking Order Theory explained

    thesis pecking order

  4. (PDF) An Analysis of Pecking Order Theory With the Analytic Hierarchy

    thesis pecking order

  5. General concept of the Pecking Order Theory.

    thesis pecking order

  6. (PDF) Testing the pecking order theory: The importance of methodology

    thesis pecking order

VIDEO

  1. Fractionalization as an alternate to charge ordering in electronic insulators

  2. PICO in Systematic Literature Review [Urdu / Hindi]

  3. Lecture 13. Out of Order Execution II and Data Flow

  4. PhD Thesis Defense

  5. Order picking using a head-up display (HUD)

  6. 21. SEMinR Series. Evaluating Structural Model

COMMENTS

  1. Pecking Order Theory, Trade-Off Theory and Determinants of Capital

    This thesis examines a variety of pecking order and trade-off asymmetric models and compares their performance with the symmetric alternative. Using data from 114 non-financial Jordanian firms (of which 62 are industrial firms and the remaining are services firms), we report evidence suggesting that firstly, equity ... 2.3.2 Empirical evidence ...

  2. An Empirical Investigation of the Pecking Order Hypothesis

    An Empirical Investigation of the Pecking Order Hypothesis. Jonathan Baskin. Jonathan Baskin is an Assistant Professor of Economics and Finance at Baruch College, City University of New York, NY. 0 Post-war corporate financial theory has focused pri- marily on the effect of risk and taxes on the valuation of cash flows with known statistical ...

  3. PDF Determinants of capital structure

    t issued to finance such deficit. An empirical result of coefficient of 0.75 from their study implied the conclusion that pecking order is a strong indicator of corporate financing behaviour. Moreover, the coefficients and significant of pecking or-der models were shown to be quite persistent while the target-adjustme

  4. PDF Pecking order theory

    This thesis studies the pecking order theory of corporate financing in North European economies. The main purpose is to find out whether listed Nordic firms follow pecking order behavior in their annual financing decisions.

  5. The Pecking Order and Financing Decisions: Evidence From Changes to

    Abstract We use the staggered introduction of a major financial-reporting regulation worldwide to study whether firms make financing decisions consistent with the pecking order theory. Exploiting cross-country and within country-year variation, we document that treated firms increase their issuance of external financing (and ultimately increase investment) after the new regime. Furthermore ...

  6. PDF Pecking order and trade-off explanations of capital structure and the

    The aim of this thesis is to provide new solutions and outcomes to the over- and under-investment problems and the information asymmetry that motivates the pecking order theory. By extending the original models, it is shown that i) the under-investment problem is caused by the debt-equity mix of the financing rather than the investment

  7. Pecking Order Model of Corporate Financing: Review of Literature

    This paper reviews li terature of the pecking order theory (POT) which is on the borderline of. financial economics and corporate finance disciplines. The ma in purpose of the literature review is ...

  8. PDF The Pecking Order Hypothesis or Static Tradeoff Theory

    Abstract This master thesis aims to test two important theories in the field of capital structure, e.g. the pecking order hypothesis and the static tradeoff theory, under the UK setting. Thus the main research question of the thesis is:" Which theory can better explain the UK non-financial firms' capital structure, the pecking order hypothesis or the static tradeoff theory?"

  9. Testing the pecking order theory of capital structure: Evidence from

    This study tests the validity of the pecking order theory at different investment levels for manufacturing firms listed on the Borsa Istanbul. The stu…

  10. Testing the pecking order theory: the importance of methodology

    The fact that the pecking order is actually a hierarchy makes research in this field more complex. Analysts should consider this special feature of the pecking order approach when analyzing the existence of the pecking order financing pattern. The methodology followed is of crucial importance in the analysis of the existence of the pecking ...

  11. Trade-Off and Pecking Order Theories of Debt

    The theory predicts that when investments exceed earnings, debt grows, and when earnings exceed investments, debt falls. Dividends are assumed to be sticky in the short term. Tests of the pecking order theory define financing deficit as investments plus change in working capital plus dividends less internal cash flow.

  12. Testing the pecking order theory: The importance of methodology

    The methodology followed is of. crucial importance in the analysis of the existence of the pecking order financing pattern. Originality/value - To the authors' knowledge, this is the first ...

  13. The Pecking Order Theory of Capital Structure: Where Do We Stand?

    The pecking order theory of corporate capital structure states that firms finance deficits with internal resources when possible. If internal funds are inadequate, firms obtain external debt.

  14. Pecking Order Theory and Innovativeness of Companies

    One of them is the pecking order theory (Myers 1984; Myers and Majluf 1984) which assumes that companies follow a hierarchy of financing sources and prefer internal financing when available, and then, if external financing is required, debt is preferred over equity. Some papers empirically verified the pecking order theory (POT), but also ...

  15. Erasmus University Thesis Repository: Aligning the Pecking order and

    Aligning the Pecking order and the Trade-off theory To what extent does the company's size and age influence the negative relation between growth opportunities and debt ratio as theorized by the Trade-off theory?

  16. Full article: Trade-off-theory vs. pecking order theory and the

    We test the assumptions of trade-off theory (TOT) and pecking order theory (POT) regarding corporate leverage. The dependent variable being the debt ratio, we apply a linear model upon a balanced p...

  17. PDF Testing the Pecking Order Theory on Technology Firms

    The pecking order theory of capital structure is among the most influential theories of corporate leverage besides the trade-off theory. According to Myers (1984) and his introduction of the pecking-order theory, firms prefer internal to external finance because of adverse selection.

  18. Capital Structure Theories and Empirical Tests: An Overview

    This chapter contains sections titled: Introduction Capital Structure Determinants Dynamic Capital Structure and Tests of Pecking Order Theory Versus Trade-Off Theory Speed of Adjustment to T...

  19. SMEs capital structure: trade-off or pecking order theory: a systematic

    Therefore, a synthesized evolution of previous works related to the capital structure of firms and SMEs is presented. Keywords Capital structure SMEs Systematic literature review Financing Pecking order theory Trade-off theory G32 G40 D21 Citation

  20. Pecking Order Theory for Government Finance

    Our model is based on Bolton and Huang (2018) in that money for governments is similar to what equity is for corporations. In contrast to their model, our model considers rational economic agents. Keywords: government finance, pecking order, capital structure, money, Ricardian Equivalence, Modigliani-Miller Proposition, asymmetric information

  21. (PDF) The Pecking Order Theory and Start-up Financing of Small and

    The above r esults of literatu re clearly consistent with the pecking order theory of capital structure and suggest that SMEs Start-up (even post s tart- up) finance in Libya tends to finance ...

  22. Pecking Order Theory

    The pecking order theory relates to a company's capital structure in that it helps explain why companies prefer to finance investment projects with internal financing first, debt second, and equity last. The pecking order theory arises from information asymmetry and explains that equity financing is the costliest and should be used as a last ...

  23. Testing the pecking order theory of capital structure: the case of

    The purpose of this paper is to examine whether or not the basic premises according to the pecking order theory provide an explanation for the capital structure mix of firms operating under Islamic principles. Pooled OLS and random effect regressions were performed to test the pecking order theory applying data from a sample of 66 Islamic firms listed on Kingdom of Saudi Arabia stock market ...